Unpacking the Conflict 567
representing labor, Republicans representing capital—which tends to make the
Democrats more protectionist and the Republicans more supportive of free trade.
Though the constituency explanation is generally true, there are divisions within each
constituency. For example, autoworkers’ and steelworkers’ unions are much more
protectionist than dockworkers’ unions because any industry with strong exports will
support free trade, whereas those that have relatively few exports but are vulnerable to
cheap imports are more likely to be protectionist. The ideological explanation focuses on
the bipartisan consensus on trade that emerged after the Great Depression, which was
seen as having been caused in part by the protective tariffs of the 1930 Smoot-Hawley
Act.^71 As with the theories of regulation, both perspectives explain part of the truth. Our
political leaders largely support a free-trade ideology (with the obvious exception of the
Trump presidency), but there are divisions along constituency lines on some legislation.
“Why
Should
I Care?”
Tax and spending policy, monetary policy, regulatory policy, and trade have more effect
on your everyday life than anything else the government does. From the taxes you pay,
to the interest rate on your student loan, to the quality of the air you breathe and the
water you drink, to the cheap consumer goods that you are able to buy, decisions by
policy makers have a tremendous effect on your economic world.
Unpacking the Conflict
There is a common perception that economic policies would work better if we could
just take politics out of the economic policy-making process. But that would be like
saying “football would be better if we could eliminate the contact” or “poker would
be better if we could take out the element of chance.” Economic policy making is
inherently political. It isn’t possible or desirable to have economic policy produced by
economists who would push and pull the levers of growth, productivity, and efficiency,
implementing their economic theories without interference from politicians. Politics
must enter into this process. Economic policy determines who wins and who loses, and
elected leaders must be involved in this process if representative democracy is to have
any meaning. This is especially true of the budget process because the redistributive
implications of taxing and spending are so clear, but as we have discussed, even
monetary policy is not insulated from politics. As discussed in the chapter opener,
winners and losers are also very evident in trade policy. Returning to the questions of
the opener, which side is right about trade policy, and what should the government
do, if anything, about trade deficits? More generally, what is the proper role of the
government in a free market economy? How do political players deal with the conflict
that is inherent in economic policy making?
Both economic theory and history tell us that we are better off with free trade than
having politicians pick winners and losers in the economy. However, there is still clearly
a role for the government in the economy through regulations, taxing and spending
policy, and monetary policy. Having the government in the economy means that
politics must have a role in economic policy making. In fact, this is guaranteed by our
system of checks and balances: Congress, the president, and to some extent the courts
Full_16_APT_64431_ch15_530-571.indd 567 15/11/18 2:35 PM