The Origins of Happiness

(Elliott) #1
Measuring Cost-Effectiveness

First there are policies involving public expenditure. The


simplest cases are when the policy generates so much sav-


ings that the net cost to public funds is negative. One exam-


ple of this is England’s new service for Improving Access to


Psychological Therapies. It can be convincingly shown that


this improves well- being at no net cost to the government.^17


But we should not of course expect every policy to pay


for itself in full. One example of a policy with a positive net


cost is the US program called Moving to Opportunity. In


this ambitious project, poor families were offered housing


vouchers to enable them to live in less disadvantaged areas.


The economic effects turned out to be negligible (except on


children who moved at a young age).^18 But the well- being


effects were significant. After 4– 7 years, mental health in-


creased against controls by 0.16 standard deviations. After


15 years, happiness had increased by 0.2 standard devia-


tions for those who used the vouchers. This corresponds


to roughly 0.4 points of life- satisfaction (0– 10). Cumulated


over say 30 years at a real discount rate of 1.5% p.a., this


is roughly 10 point- years of life- satisfaction (0– 10). The net


cost per family was $3,700 (and even less per person).^19 So


the cost per additional point- year of happiness was under


$300— a real bargain.


Another example is a policy to provide cement floors to


peasant houses in Mexico.^20 Treatment households were of-


fered (and all accepted) cement floors; control households


were not. After 3 years, mothers were asked Are you satisfied


with your quality of life (1 = very satisfied or satisfied; 0 =


fair or unsatisfied). The mean for the control was 0.60 and


the effect of treatment was +0.11 points— equivalent to an


upward shift in mean z- score of roughly 0.22— or 0.4 points


of life- satisfaction. The cost was $150 per household. If the

Free download pdf