The Washington Post - 19.08.2019

(Rick Simeone) #1

MONDAY, AUGUST 19 , 2019. THE WASHINGTON POST EZ RE A


C


hances are, if you live in a city,
Uber and Lyft have changed
your life. Even my 74-year-old
mother now semi-frequently
uses Uber to get around — this, a
woman with whom I once spent
45 minutes on the telephone, trying to
coach her through minimizing a win-
dow on her desktop.
As advances go, Uber and Lyft aren’t
quite up there with indoor plumbing
and central heating, but they’re still
definitely an improvement over the
prior status quo: more reliable, more
available and cheaper than taxi ser-
vices, especially for remote and low-
income areas. And, now, they’re offer-
ing urban dwellers bikes and electric
scooters, as well as cars. Even when
they eventually stop burning investor
cash to subsidize those services, being
able to spontaneously hail a ride from
your phone — or grab a scooter for the
morning commute, or pick up a few
extra bucks as a driver — will noticeably
improve millions of people’s lives.
Uber and Lyft are everything we love
about capitalism. And writ large, theirs
is the story of the capitalist revolution
that has over the past few centuries
raised us from short-lived squalor to
lives of comparative peace, wealth and
leisure. Just 170 years ago, my ancestors
fled a famine that denuded Ireland of
roughly a quarter of its population. By
contrast, their descendants today fret
about advancing avoirdupois, a real
estate bubble and the high cost of
space-age diagnostic scans.
The journey between 19th-century
hardship and today’s abundance was
composed of many steps, most of them
guided by the invisible hand of the
market. Markets funneled resources to
promising ideas, many of them bad,

some of them pure genius, and then
winnowed out the bad ones. That itera-
tive process of incremental improve-
ment has brought us to the here and
now. We can reasonably hope that it
will propel our grandchildren further
still, to something that would seem to
us an unimaginable paradise.
I won’t say I think of this every time I
open my Lyft app; I do say that I
probably should. But recently, I’ve been
thinking that though Uber and Lyft are
everything we love about capitalism,
they are also everything we hate.
Consider the difference between the
corporate cultures of these two firms.
Uber’s early chief executive, Travis Ka-
lanick, was a tech-bro outlaw whose
desire to disrupt the taxi industry may
have started with the time he was
forced to jump out of a cab after a
heated altercation with the driver. Dur-
ing the company’s turbulent early
years, Kalanick staged equally belliger-
ent confrontations with local govern-
ments, allegedly tolerated rampant sex-
ual harassment and discrimination
within his company, and pitched his
services to the affluent as “a conven-
ient, and classy ride.”
Lyft was like Uber’s kindly hippie
cousin. Its founders are explicitly ideal-
istic about Lyft’s mission to eliminate
the environmental and financial costs
of personal car ownership. While Uber
initially focused on fancy black cars,
Lyft let people drive their modest older-
model sedans and initially stuck mus-
taches on the front of the car to reassure
passengers that Lyft was goofily benev-
olent. They invited passengers to ride
up front with the driver, like a friend
rather than a customer. They took a
conciliatory stance toward regulation.
Uber and Lyft were about as differ-

ent as two companies in fundamentally
the same business could be. But at this
point, from the customer perspective,
they’re barely different. They offer the
same services, for roughly the same
price, in many of the same markets.
Worse, Uber, the aggressively merce-
nary firm, has a higher market share
than the idealists.
This, too, is the invisible hand of the
market, driving everyone in the same
direction. As markets like to do, be-
cause markets tend to reward scale.
Scale, in turn, rewards the lowest
common denominator that everyone
will accept, which means the homog-
enous and ubiquitous. And because
idealistic values are costly, and decid-
edly not homogenous across large
groups of people, they are rarely re-
warded the way storybooks tell us they
ought to be.
Which may explain why elements of
both left and right are nearing open
revolt against the whole idea of mar-
kets. Market innovation is highest in a
tech sector that tends toward scale even
more sharply than its industrial fore-
bears: the efficient number of firms
providing the services of a Facebook, a
Google or an Amazon — and maybe an
Uber or a Lyft — is probably one. (Ama-
zon founder and chief executive Jeff
Bezos also owns The Post.)
The obvious rejoinder to this com-
plaint is that “the market” is simply us,
collectively. It is failing to reward cer-
tain things because we are failing to
reward them, at least in sufficiently
large numbers. But then, perhaps that’s
exactly why they make us so uncom-
fortable: because markets reflect back
to us what we are, instead of what we’d
like to be.
Twitter: @asymmetricinfo

MEGAN MCARDLE

Uber and Lyft: Everything we


love and hate about capitalism


GENE J. PUSKAR/ASSOCIATED PRESS
A Lyft logo is installed on a driver's car in Pittsburgh.

T


here are two quite different paths
toward change in the 2020 elec-
tions. One would involve getting
rid of President Trump but leav-
ing Washington gridlocked. The other
would see a Democratic president elected
with a Democratic Congress. For the first
time in a decade, progressives, with some
help from moderates, would have a
chance to govern and begin to push back
against the conservative takeover of the
federal judiciary.
It will all come down to the fight to
control the Senate.
And the Democrats’ chances of win-
ning a majority took a modest step for-
ward last week when former Colorado
governor John Hickenlooper ended his
campaign for the Democratic presiden-
tial nomination and signaled he was con-
sidering taking on Republican Sen. Cory
Gardner. While there are already other
potentially strong Democrats in that con-
test, polls show Hickenlooper leading
Gardner by double digits.
If Democrats won the White House,
they would need a net three-seat gain to
control the Senate with the vote of a
Democratic vice president. It’s difficult to
imagine this happening without the de-
feat of the three most vulnerable Republi-
can incumbents, Gardner and Sens. Susan
Collins (R-Maine) and Martha McSally
(R-Ariz.). Alabama Sen. Doug Jones (D)
faces a very tough reelection campaign in
a deeply Republican, pro-Trump state. A
Jones loss would move the Democrats’
victory line to four pickups.
Their chances of getting there depend
in part on whether Montana’s Democrat-
ic Gov. Steve Bullock decides to end his
own presidential candidacy to take on
Republican Sen. Steve Daines. It’s hard to

see any other Democrat beating Daines.
Bullock — as he never tires of pointing out
— has shown he can run far ahead of his
party’s ticket. Bullock has insisted he
doesn’t want to be a senator, but Demo-
cratic Senate strategists, with an accent
on hope, sense a softening in Bullock’s
stance on the Senate.
Hickenlooper’s decision to withdraw
points to two important dynamics in the
Democratic presidential race. The first is
that former vice president Joe Biden is
blocking the emergence of any other
moderate or center-left candidate. Ab-
sent a Biden collapse in the next few
months, there will be little room for
candidates such as Sens. Amy Klobuchar
of Minnesota or Michael F. Bennet of
Colorado.
It was striking that a Quinnipiac Uni-
versity poll this month found that Biden
was winning just 19 percent of Democrats
who said they were “very liberal” and
28 percent who called themselves “some-
what liberal.” But he was taking 43 per-
cent among those who called themselves
moderate or conservative.
This leads to the other dynamic: Ag-
gressively taking on the left, as Hicken-
looper did, is not, for now at least, a
winning strategy for more moderate
presidential candidates. This is partly
because their real competition comes
from Biden but also because progressive
Democrats have shown themselves far
more open to moderate candidates in
Senate and House races than in the presi-
dential race. Progressives have been will-
ing to make pragmatic judgments about
who is best positioned to win a given
Senate or House seat but want to make a
strong statement in the presidential con-
test. Thus, in the same Quinnipiac poll,

Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D-Mass.) led
Biden by more than 2 to 1 among very
liberal Democrats.
It’s notable that in his dignified with-
drawal video, Hickenlooper stressed
three issues that appeal across the Demo-
crats’ moderate/liberal divide and also to
swing voters: lowering prescription drug
costs, dealing with climate change and
taking action on guns. He sounded like a
Senate candidate.
If Senate Democrats are hopeful that
Hickenlooper and possibly Bullock could
help them take the Senate, they are also
looking to what they call “the Heller
Effect” to get them the rest of the seats
they need. In 2018, Nevada’s Republican
Sen. Dean Heller lost in part because he
was cross-pressured between showing
support for Trump to rally his Republican
base and demonstrating independence
from Trump to attract middle-of-the-road
voters.
This political inconstancy didn’t work
for Heller, and Democrats think the same
neither-one-thing-nor-the-other dynam-
ic could hurt Republican Sens. Thom
Tillis in North Carolina and Joni Ernst in
Iowa — as well as Gardner, Collins and
McSally. Tillis was already embarrassed
earlier this year when he wrote a Post
op-ed opposing Trump’s emergency dec-
laration to build a border wall and then
turned around and voted with Trump on
the same issue. His flip-flop left both sides
unhappy.
As for Hickenlooper, he often seemed
uncomfortable as a presidential candi-
date but was eloquent whenever he talked
about his bipartisan achievements as gov-
ernor of Colorado. It’s an approach that
could serve him well as he heads home.
Twitter: @EJDionne

E.J. DIONNE JR.

Real change depends on the Senate


W


hat is striking about the latest
bouts of financial turmoil —
the recent wild swings in
global stock and bond mar-
kets — is that they provide a sobering
reminder of the potential hazards of eco-
nomic instability. There are parallels be-
tween the present tumultuous situation
and past episodes of economic disrup-
tion, including the Great Depression of
the 1930s.
Just for the record: This is not a fore-
cast of another Depression, when annual
U.S. unemployment peaked at about
25 percent in 1933. For the moment, we
are not anywhere near that level of dis-
tress. Still, if a deeper crisis ensues, Presi-
dent Trump’s strident economic national-
ism will be partially blamed, because he
ignored the lessons of history.
The name that comes to mind is
Charles Kindleberger, an eminent eco-
nomic historian of the post-World War II
era who taught for years at the Massachu-
setts Institute of Technology and was a
prolific author of books and articles. One
of his masterpieces was “The World in
Depression, 1929-1939.”
The crux of Kindleberger’s thesis was
that the underlying cause of the Depres-
sion was a vacuum of leadership. By this,
he meant that Britain — which had pro-
vided that leadership in the 19th century
— had been so weakened by World War I
that it could no longer perform that
function in the 1920s and early 1930s.
Meanwhile, the United States — which
would fill that role after World War II —
was not ready to do so.
In this context, the dominant country
would keep its markets open to imports,
so the trading system would not collapse
under the weight of mounting protec-
tionism. Another requirement was that
the leading country (the “hegemon”) had
to have the financial strength so it could
lend to banks and other needy borrowers
during a crisis so that the financial sys-
tem, the repository of much wealth,
would not self-destruct.
In the recent foreword of the latest
version of Kindleberger’s book, econo-
mists J. Bradford DeLong and Barry
Eichengreen of the University of Califor-
nia at Berkeley put it this way:
“The root of Europe’s and the world’s
problems was the absence of a benevolent
hegemon: a dominant economic power
able and willing to take the interests of
smaller powers and the operation of the
larger international system into account
by stabilizing the flow of spending
through the global [economy]... by act-
ing as a lender and consumer of last
resort.”

Kindleberger’s own explanation is
similar:
“The 1929 depression was so wide, so
deep and so long because the internation-
al economic system was rendered unsta-
ble.... When every country turned to
protect its national private interest, the
world’s public interest went down the
drain, and with it the private interests of
all.”
Flash forward. Look around. Leader-
ship is conspicuous by its absence. Na-
tions pursue their self-identified private
interests. The United States and China —
the world’s two largest economies — are
engaged in a bitter trade war that hurts
both countries. The British are poised to
leave the European Union (Brexit), with
what consequences no one knows. At
home, the Federal Reserve is under re-
lentless assault by Trump, making its job
doubly difficult, even granting that the
best monetary policy is a legitimate sub-
ject of debate and disagreement.
What about Germany, Europe’s tradi-
tional powerhouse? In the past year, its
industrial production is down about
5 percent, says economist Desmond Lach-
man of the American Enterprise Insti-
tute. If Germany does not change its
“rigid policy view on the need to balance
their budget under all circumstances,
both Germany and Europe should brace
themselves for a hard economic landing,”
he argues.
Economic leadership is a two-step
process, each difficult. First, you must
conceptualize the nature of the crisis;
then you must devise and implement
remedies that prevent it from
worsening.
In the 2007 to 2009 financial crisis,
that is what happened. The administra-
tions of George W. Bush and Barack
Obama recognized that the financial sys-
tem might collapse, as panicked deposi-
tors and investors withdrew their funds.
The remedy, organized on a global scale,
was to pump money into the system until
confidence returned.
Trump officials don’t seem to think
Kindleberger matters. Their pursuit of
“greatness” might prove self-destructive.
The good news is that the financial sys-
tem is stronger now, meaning it has more
capital to absorb losses, than in 2008. The
bad news is that private debt levels in
many countries, including the United
States and China, are high. If too many
borrowers default, losses may still cripple
the financial system.
There’s the old cliche that those who
don’t remember history are condemned
to repeat it. Let’s hope that’s not true this
time.

ROBERT J. SAMUELSON

Learning from


the Great Depression


BY FREDERICK W. SMITH,
WILLIAM BROCK
AND CHARLENE BARSHEFSKY

P


resident Trump’s trade policy has
been controversial for any num-
ber of reasons, but it has made
Americans think seriously about
trade for the first time in a generation.
The president believes that much of our
trade has been unfair — that other coun-
tries have taken advantage of us. He does
not remind Americans that trade has
become an essential element of our pros-
perity, accounting for more than 27 per-
cent of our economic output and support-
ing 1 in 5 U.S. jobs.
Today, the trading system is under
attack from two directions. On one hand,
we face assertive economies such as Chi-
na that have a limited and largely mercan-
tilist stake in the system and have chosen
to press forward through a program of
state-directed capitalism. At home, many
Americans feel the policies that promised
to advance their economic interests have
failed them. Polls show Americans under-
stand that trade can be a positive force,
but at the same time, they worry that their
personal situations have not improved.
Only the top 20 percent of U.S. house-
holds have fully recovered from the 2007
to 2009 recession. Progressives see trade
agreements benefiting large companies
rather than workers, while conservatives
are reluctant to cede sovereignty through
international agreements. Both left and
right are firing at the center instead of
trying to build consensus.
The United States seems to be losing
both these arguments. Internationally,
we have rested on our record instead of
defending the rules we created and chal-
lenging those who reject the rules and the
values that underlie them. Congress has
failed to legislate — and the executive
branch has failed to effectively adminis-
ter — programs that would provide new
opportunities for workers displaced by
trade or technology. When the answer to
China’s challenge is containment rather
than competition, it demonstrates a loss
of confidence in our ability to compete
and win when engaging with the world.
The chief arrow in the president’s quiv-
er has been tariffs, but they are not an
effective weapon. In the short term, they
are a tax on U.S. consumers. The New York
Federal Reserve Bank estimates that, to
date, the administration’s tariff policy has
cost the median earner $831 per year,
nearly offsetting the $930 per year benefit
from the 2017 tax cut. In the long term,
tariffs raise costs for U.S. businesses and
consumers, eroding our competitive ad-
vantage.
We should instead play to our

strengths. First, we must recognize our
success in creating and leading the global
system that has been good for us as well as
the world, maintaining peace and stabili-
ty, and creating economic opportunity.
Our willingness to lead was founded on
our economic strength: the most produc-
tive workers and the best technology and
world-class companies working together
in a favorable policy environment to pro-
mote growth and prosperity here at home
and around the world.
If we withdraw from the world or
alienate our friends and allies, we lose our
ability to shape the international envi-
ronment. Healthy, growing economies
throughout the world benefit the United
States, directly through expanded trade
and indirectly by promoting peace and
stability according to mutually agreed
rules. The United States needs to contin-
ue to guide the system as 95 percent of the
world’s population and 80 percent of its
purchasing power lie outside our bor-
ders. Engagement is essential to our sur-
vival; trade is an integral part of our
engagement.
How do we reestablish a pro-trade
consensus here at home while respond-
ing more effectively to the global eco-
nomic landscape? We have to fight for it.
We have the advantage of strong domestic
economic growth, but we need more.
Internationally, we must maintain our
support for a rules-based trading system,
avoid a cycle of competitive currency
devaluations and pursue additional mul-
tilateral agreements that set rules for the
new economy. In the United States, we
must revitalize our culture of innovation
and take back our leadership in research
and development. We also must protect
our intellectual property, which sustains
our economy and strengthens our nation-
al security; and we must ensure that
current and future American workers are
prepared for a world where work will
require more agility and new skills.
Several presidential administrations,
including the current one, have found
that withdrawing from the world threat-
ens our growth. The United States must
recommit itself to continued economic
engagement with the rest of the world,
not isolation and trade wars. The Center
for Strategic and International Studies is
launching a new Commission on Affirm-
ing American Leadership. As co-chairs of
this effort, we look forward to exploring
these issues and charting a path forward
for our nation. The time is right.

Frederick W. Smith is chairman and CEO of
FedEx. William Brock was U.S. trade
representative (USTR) under President Ronald
Reagan. Charlene Barshefsky was USTR
under President Bill Clinton.

Recommitting to trade

Free download pdf