The Boston Globe - 07.08.2019

(Ann) #1
A10 Editorial The Boston Globe WEDNESDAY, AUGUST 7, 2019

I


t has never been more popular to work fromhome.
It used to be nothing morethan a nice job perk —
like free coffee or being allowed to bring your dog to
the office. But the state government has now
identified telecommuting as a policy tool with
potential to ease our record-high levels of congestion.
As part of a broader $18 billion transportation investment
bill unveiledlast week, Governor Charlie Baker is proposinga
new tax credit to encourage companies to let employees work
from home. Fewer cars on the road during the workweek
equals less traffic for everybody. What’s not to like?
Unfortunately, the value is not quitethat straightforward.
Baker’s telework subsidy is worth pursuing — but only if it’s
part of a broader plan to tackle congestion that includes
stronger investments in bus and rail transit, and more
targeted traffic-reduction policies such as congestion pricing.
First, the details. Baker is proposing a $2,000 tax break,
which would go to the employer, per each worker who begins
telecommutingon or after Jan. 1, 2020. In other words,
companies that have employees working fromhome right
now wouldn’t be able to claimthe tax credit — these have to
be new telecommuters. The total subsidies would be capped
at $50 million a year.
Nationally, telecommuting is on the rise. According to a
Globe story last week, roughly half the US labor force works
from home at least once a month, and the number of non-
self-employed workers who telecommute at least half the
time increased159 percent between 2005 and 2017. In
Massachusetts, only 4.7 percent of the workforce

telecommutes full time, lower than in 19 other states.
Moreover, according to Baker’s remarks whenhe
introducedthe proposal,“Nearly 70 percentof
Massachusetts’ workers report driving to workalone in a
vehicle.” Lest we forget, Boston had the worst rush-hour
traffic last year, according to one report. On average, Boston
drivers lost 164 hours in peak traffic periods.
So what’s the harm of enacting a policy that has the
potential to encourage less driving? It has to do with who the
tax subsidy benefits most, and whether it is
focused and cost-effective.
Most beneficiaries of the program will
likely be white-collar workers, argued Chris
Dempsey,directoroftheadvocacygroup
Transportation for Massachusetts. Workers
in managerial positions are more likely to
have the ability and flexibility to work from
home, as opposed to restaurant or
construction workers. (Of course, the
argumentgoes, blue-collar workers will
benefitindirectlybyencounteringless
clogged roads.)
Dempsey also points out that the telecommuting subsidy,
unlike state spending on mass transit, won’t benefit from
scale — it’ll always cost $2,000 per telecommuter per year.
“Transit is different. The state’s contribution is flat, not per-
rider, so as ridershipgrows the state contribution per trip
actually goes down. That’s why state policies that increase
transit usage — like dedicated bus lanes and congestion

pricing — are such great public policies.”
It’s also a potentiallyscattershot approach: As written, the
bill would not necessarilyensure that the workers who start
telecommutingwere previously driving on heavily congested
roads or during peak hours.
Of course, the politics of transportation reformcannot be
ignored. Baker seems to be contradicting himself with the
telework proposal. Last year, he vetoed a widely supported
pilot program to test congestion pricing, or smarter tolling, on
the grounds that it needed to be studied
first. And yet, the benefits of a telework tax
credit on traffic have gone largely unproven.
Congestion pricing is far more targeted, and
only applies to drivers on the roads and at
the times where traffic is worst.
This is not to downplay telecommuting’s
potentialimpact on traffic. It’s a concept
that resonates with people because of its
simplicity. But that’s exactly why flexible
work arrangements should be deployedas
modest, narrow measures to see a dent in
congestion. (For instance, officialsin Tokyo
are implementing a “work fromhome” two-week program to
manage the massive crowdsthat will burden the city’s
subway system during the 2020 Olympics next summer.)
As one tool among many, a targeted state policy to
encourage teleworking makes sense. Alone,it’s inequitable
and won’t help address the needsof thousandsof the state’s
commuters.

Baker’s telework credit isn’t enough, but it’s a start

Opinion

BOSTONGLOBE.COM/OPINION

Editorial

abcde
Founded 1872

JOHNW. HENRY
Publisher

VINAY MEHRA
President

LINDA PIZZUTIHENRY
ManagingDirector

SENIORDEPUTY
MANAGING EDITORS
Mark S. Morrow
Jason M. TuoheyDigital Platforms and Audience Engagement

DEPUTY MANAGING EDITORS
Marjorie PritchardEditorial Page
David DahlPrint and Operations
Felice BelmanLocal News and Features
Veronica ChaoLiving/Arts

BUSINESSMANAGEMENT
Dhiraj NayarChief Financial Officer
Dan KrockmalnicGeneral Counsel
Kayvan SalmanpourChiefCommercial Officer
Anthony BonfiglioVice President, Engineering
Claudia HendersonChief Human Resources Officer
Jane BowmanVice President, Marketing & Strategic
Partnerships
Dale CarpenterSenior Vice President, Print Operations

Charles H. TaylorFounder & Publisher 1873-
William O. TaylorPublisher 1921-
Wm.Davis TaylorPublisher 1955-
William O. TaylorPublisher 1978-
Benjamin B. TaylorPublisher 1997-
Richard H. GilmanPublisher 1999-
P. Steven AinsleyPublisher 2006-
Christopher M. MayerPublisher 2009-
Laurence L. WinshipEditor 1955-
Thomas WinshipEditor 1965-

BRIANMcGRORY
Editor

JENNIFERPETER
ManagingEditor

T

here was a time, in the aftermath of the
financial crisis, when central bankers
were“the only game in town.” In a book
with that title, published in January 2016,
economist MohamedEl-Erian warned
that, with theirexotic crisis-fighting
measures —zero interest rates,
quantitative easing, forward guidance — the central bankers
risked overreaching.
This was prescient. Three years on, the men and women
who make monetary policy are very far from the only game
in town. Now they’re the ones being gamed.
Last Wednesday, Federal Reserve Chair Jerome “Jay”
Powell explained at a press conference why he and his
colleagues had decided to cut interest rates by a quarter of 1
percent. Giventhat the economy is still growingat a
reasonable 2.1 percent and has the lowest unemployment
rate since December1969,the decision took a bit of
explaining. Powell’s best argument, aside from persistently
low inflation? “Trade policy uncertainty,” which he referred
to at least two dozen times, twice as often as the other
excuse (“weak global growth”).
Overthe past year, President Trump has repeatedly
criticized the Fed for wanting to hike rates and then for not
cutting rates enough. His response
to the Fed’s quarter-point cut was
swift. The very next day he tweeted
his intention to “start, on
September 1st, putting a small
additional Tariff of 10% on the
remaining 300 Billion Dollars of
goods and products coming from
China into our Country.”
New York and Washington,
D.C., are full of commentators who
wentto Harvard, Yale, and Princeton (which Powell
attended) and considerthemselves muchsmarter than
Donald Trump.They snigger when he calls himself a “stable
genius.” But this president is crazy like a fox. His behavior
may seem nuts or just plain dumb,but it is in fact calculated
to outsmart the Ivy League types.
The Fed says it’s cutting rates because of trade
uncertainty that Trump himselfhas almost single-handedly
caused. But it’s only doing a lousyquarter-percent. The
crazy-fox response is to threaten yet more tariffs on Chinese
goods on Sept. 1, two weeks before the next meeting of the
Federal OpenMarkets Committee, which sets the Fed’s
interest rate.
Now tell me who is the only game in town.
Officially, the readiness of central bankers to cut rates
preemptively to avert recession, or at least to scrap rate
hikes and further “quantitative tightening,” reflects a
fundamental shift in economic thinking. The post-2008-
assumption was that the goal was to fight the crisis and then
“normalize,” i.e., to get rates back up to pre-crisis levels. But
the counter-argument — that we face a problem of secular
stagnation, not just a cyclical hangover — appearsto have
won the day. No one now believes that interest rates can
return to where they were before 2008.

At the same time, there has beena widespread
abandonmentof the old principles of fiscal policy. Now even
Olivier Blanchard, formerly chief economist at the
International Monetary Fund, says that rising public debts
are less of a problem than used to be thought. This is not
something I ever expected to hear from a senior fellow of the
PetersonInstitute for International Affairs, but then Pete
Peterson— the lifelong fiscal conservative whose namethe
institute bears— died last year.
These shifts in monetary and fiscal theory are a huge
stroke of luck for populists in power. (I refuse to
countenance the disgraceful idea that they are in fact a
rationalization of the central bankers’ rapidly dwindling
political independence.) For whatever reason, the Federal
Open Markets Committee has becomethe Committee to
Reelect Trump. This isn’t because Trump has successfully
brow-beaten the Fed staff with his tweets, or so they insist.
It’s because their estimates of the “natural rate of interest”
are just really, really low.
And it’s a similar story in Britain, Europe, and Brazil.
Give the populists theirdue. They intuitively knew that
therewas something crazy (in the non-fox-like sense) about
raising interest rates and trying to balance budgets in the

post-crisis world, just as they understood that votershad
tired of ever freertrade and rising immigration rates. It was
the eggheads (myself among them, I admit) who wanted
sound money and austerity.
Could anything breakthis trend, whereby falling interest
rates and painless deficits help populists stay in power? One
answer I can think of is a majorwar, which has tended to be
the thing, historically, that drives inflation expectationsand
interest rates upward. But that, too, is something the
populists have pretty muchruledout. They saw what
became of another set of eggheads — the neoconservatives
— when they decided to revive war as an instrument of
policy after 9/11.
But another game-changer would be an election surprise.
Markets seem to love a right-wing government
unconstrained by monetary and fiscal rules. They may feel
differently if a left-wing governmentinherits this lack of
constraint. The difference between technocracy and
democracy is that there’s always more than one gamein
town.And not all crazy foxes are on the right.

Niall Ferguson is a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution at
Stanford University.

NIALLFERGUSON

Trump’s crazy tariffs have outfoxed the Fed

The presidenthas

turnedthetables

ononce-mighty

central bankers.

Fewercarsonthe

roadduringthe

workweekequals

lesstraffic for

everybody. What’s

notto like?

ILLUSTRATION BY LESLEYBECKER/GLOBESTAFF; ADOBE; GLOBE FILE PHOTO
Free download pdf