Skeptic March 2020

(Wang) #1

Monopoly


and Monopolies


What Board Games Teach Us About Capitalism


and How to Modify It


BYJONATHAN KAY

22SKEPTIC MAGAZINE volume 25 number 1 2020

Imagine that you are in the late stages of a game
of Monopoly, battling it out against a lone remaining
opponent. You each control a bunch of expensive
properties, all loaded with hotels. Both of you also are
cash-poor, with no spare properties left to mortgage.
Every roll of the dice carries high stakes. If your oppo-
nent lands on one of your hotels, the only way he can
pay the rent will be to sell off his own hotels at a 50-
percent discount (because that is how the rules of Mo-
nopolywork), and vice versa. This means that the first
player who lands on an opponent’s hotel will not just
lose a lot of money: He will also lose the assets he
needs to earn that money back. In real life, the analogy
would be the poor worker in Victorian Britain who,
unable to pay a small debt, goes to debtor’s prison,
which further compromises his ability to earn a liveli-
hood, and so pushes his family deeper into complete
destitution.
“Well, that’s capitalism,” you might say. Perhaps.
We will get to that later. For now, I want to emphasize
that this aspect of Monopoly—the poor get poorer,
while the rich get richer—is not only typical of laissez-
faire economics. It is also characteristic of a certain dy-
namic observed in nature, engineering, and human

relationships, one that mathematicians sometimes de-
scribe as unstable equilibrium.
Take a simple physical metaphor: a marble rest-
ing at the bottom of a salad bowl is going to exhibit a
stableequilibrium—because small movements in any
direction will push the marble up against the walls of
the bowl, and the marble will roll back toward its start
position, also known as its equilibrium point.
If the salad bowl is turned upside down, however,
and the marble is placed at the top of it, the marble
will exhibit an unstableequilibrium: Even if the
marble is balanced perfectly on top of the bowl, and
so remains temporarily motionless, a nudge in any
direction will lead to a feedback loop whereby the
marble rolls off the bowl, moving slowly at first and
then accelerating downward. In general, a stable equi-
librium tends to correct itself, restoring the balance of
offsetting forces that held it in check to begin with;
while an unstable equilibrium tends to destabilize in
one direction or another, until the system in some way
collapses or reaches a different stable equilibrium.
Now let us return to Monopoly. You and your
imaginary opponent are moving your tokens around
the board, seeking to avoid one another’s hotels. In a

EXCERPT

Free download pdf