Introduction to Corporate Finance

(Tina Meador) #1
7: Risk, Return and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

In Figure 7.4, the investor’s portfolio lies up and to the right of the market portfolio at point B.
At this point, we must stop and make a crucial observation. If it is true, as the preceding example

shows, that a portfolio with a beta of 0.5 offers an expected return of 7%, then, in equilibrium, it must


also be true that any individual security with a beta of 0.5 offers the same return. To understand this


claim, examine point C in Figure 7.4. This point represents a share with a beta of 0.5 and an expected


return of less than 7%. Rational investors who own C will sell it, because they can create an equally risky


portfolio that offers a higher return, by combining Treasury notes and the market portfolio. As investors


sell asset C, its price will fall. We know that prices and returns of financial assets move in opposite


directions (for example, if a bond’s price falls, its yield rises), so as the price of C falls, its expected return


rises until it reaches 7%.


Similarly, consider point D in the figure. Point D represents an asset with a beta of 0.5 but an


expected return greater than 7%. This asset is a true bargain, because it offers investors a higher rate of


return than they can earn on a 50–50 portfolio of Treasury notes and shares, without requiring them to


take on extra risk. Investors will rush to buy share D, and their buying pressure will drive up the price


and push down the return of share D. As soon as the expected return on D reaches 7%, the market once


again reaches equilibrium.


Figure 7.4 therefore plots the relationship between betas and expected returns for individual


securities as well as for portfolios. This relationship is called the security market line, and the equation of


this line is the fundamental risk and return relationship predicted by the capital asset pricing model (CAPM).


The CAPM says that the expected return on any asset (i), denoted by E(ri), depends on the risk-free rate(rf),


the asset’s beta (bi) and the market risk premium (given by the excess expected return of the market (E(rm))


compared to the risk free rate.^11


Eq. 7.5 E(ri) = rf + bi(E(rm) – rf)


11 ‘i ’ is standard notation to suggest any asset, rather than a specific asset. ‘ri ’ refers to the return of this asset i. ‘E(ri)’ refers to the expected
return of the asset i.


William Sharpe, Stanford
University, Co-founder,
Financial Engines
‘To the extent that there
is a premium for bearing
risk, it is a premium for
bearing the risk of doing
badly in bad times.’
See the entire interview on
the CourseMate website.

Source: Cengage Learning

COURSEMATE
SMART VIDEO

finance in practice

CFO FORECASTS OF THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM


The expected risk premium on the market is an
important component of the CAPM, but how does
one know what the expected market risk premium
is? One way to estimate that premium is to ask
CFOs what return they expect shares to earn
relative to safe assets such as Treasury notes or, in
the US, Treasury bonds or bills. The chart below
shows the market risk premium that American
CFOs said they expected (looking 10 years into

the future) when they responded to the quarterly
Duke University CFO Survey. From 2001 to 2011
(1st quarter), CFOs’ estimates of the market risk
premium averaged about 3.5%, but their forecasts
fluctuated over time, ranging from a low of about
2.4% to a high of 4.75%. In general, these forecasts
suggest that CFOs expect a lower market risk
premium than the long-run historical average of
7.5% presented in Chapter 6.
> >

capital asset pricing
model (CAPM)
States that the expected
return on a specific asset
equals the risk-free rate plus a
premium that depends on the
asset’s beta and the expected
risk premium on the market
portfolio
Free download pdf