Introduction to Corporate Finance

(Tina Meador) #1
15: Payout Policy

is to determine whether a given company has an optimal (value-maximising) payout policy and, if so,


how that policy should be set. As we proceed, you may notice a puzzling fact. Almost all the real-world


issues we incorporate – such as taxes, transactions costs for issuing new securities and uncertainty about


a company’s investment opportunities – argue against the payment of cash dividends. Yet the majority of


established companies make dividend payments in most years.


15- 4a PERSONAL INCOME TAXES


When the personal tax rate on dividends is higher than the tax rate on capital gains, the result is clear


cut: companies wishing to distribute cash to shareholders should not pay cash dividends, but instead


should repurchase shares. This offers investors the choice of either receiving cash in a tax-favoured form


(as a capital gain) or forgoing the cash altogether by not selling shares, and thus seeing their share values


increase as their fractional ownership increases.


Why don’t we see more companies substituting share repurchase programs for cash dividend


payments? There are a few answers to this question. First, as we have seen, many Australian companies


have been repurchasing their shares during the past 10 years. Second, the companies that initiate share


repurchase programs are the same companies that also make large cash dividend payments. In some


countries, legislation can be a key factor. For example, in the US, the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) has


the power to rule that a given company’s share repurchase program is merely an attempt to avoid taxes.


The IRS can impose the higher personal income tax rates on all income received by investors. The actual


importance of this rule in deterring repurchases is questionable, however, because the IRS almost never


invokes it.


In Australia, the dividend imputation system reduces the impact of taxation of dividend income in


comparison to countries where this is not available. (Investors only pay, or receive, the net difference


between the franking credits and their personal income tax attributable to a dividend payment).


Furthermore, although there are various exemptions in place, the tax rate applied to capital gains in


Australia is simply the marginal income tax rate applicable to the investor at the time the capital gain is


crystallised. Thus, although there may be timing differences and a few exemptions in place, in Australia,


the tax rates applicable to cash dividends or share repurchases are the same.


On balance, incorporating personal taxes into our model does not help us understand why companies


pay dividends. However, tax effects may account for some of the patterns we observe, such as the rise in


share repurchase programs in Australia, the US and other industrialised countries.


15- 4b TRADING AND OTHER TRANSACTIONS COSTS


If personal taxes cannot explain observed dividend payments, what about transaction costs of issuing and


trading shares? Trading costs affect expected dividend payouts in two potentially offsetting ways. First, if


investors find it costly to sell just a few shares to generate cash – to create homemade dividends – then


they may be willing to pay a premium for shares that regularly pay dividends. Regular cash dividend


payments are a costless way to receive a cash return on an investor’s share portfolio. This cash could be


used either for consumption or for rebalancing the investor’s portfolio. In spite of this, a transaction cost


argument cannot easily explain why aggregate dividend payouts have remained fairly high, even as share


markets have become vastly more efficient and the costs of trading have declined dramatically.


The second effect of transaction costs on dividend payments is completely negative. This relates


to a company’s need to replace cash paid out as dividends with cash obtained through new share sales.

Free download pdf