Introduction to Corporate Finance

(Tina Meador) #1
ONLINE CHAPTER

23 -1b THE HEDGING DECISION


Although it is clear that the corporate demand for hedging and risk-management products has grown
dramatically in recent years, it is less clear why a public company would choose to hedge at all. In
chapters 13 and 15, we learned that, in perfect markets, investors can effectively unwind managers’
decisions regarding capital structure and dividends. Modigliani and Miller^1 showed that managers
could not increase company value by choosing an optimal capital structure or dividend policy. The same
conclusion applies to risk management when markets are perfect. If managers use derivative securities
to hedge a particular risk, investors can trade on their own to undo what managers have done. The
explanation for companies’ hedging activities could be either that markets are imperfect or that managers
hedge for their own benefit rather than for the benefit of shareholders. This section discusses the various
potential motivations for hedging and possible hedging strategies.

Motivations for Hedging


The motivations for buying insurance are similar to those for hedging. However, there are some crucial
differences. By purchasing insurance, a corporation benefits from the insurance company’s expertise, in
terms of its ability to evaluate and price certain types of risks. Therefore, insurance companies have a
comparative advantage in bearing these sources of risk. Similarly, insurance companies have the ability
to process claims more efficiently and effectively than other corporations. For example, insurance
companies have expertise in negotiating, settling and providing legal representation in liability suits.
Hedging market-wide sources of risk, on the other hand, does not seem to provide any real service
other than reduced volatility. In addition, this risk reduction is costly in terms of the resources required
to implement an effective risk-management program. There are direct costs associated with hedging –
transactions costs of buying and selling forwards, futures, options and swaps – and indirect costs in the
form of managers’ time and expertise.
According to modern hedging theory, value-maximising companies hedge because hedging can
increase company value in several ways. The principal reason most companies hedge, however, is
to reduce the likelihood of financial distress. Figure 23.2 illustrates the impact of hedging on the
likelihood of financial distress, showing the range of possible cash flows for the company in a given period
and the associated probability distribution. If the company’s cash flows are below point A on the x-axis,
the company experiences financial distress. By hedging, the company is able to reduce the probability of
the company’s cash flows being below point A.
Reducing the likelihood of financial distress benefits the company by also reducing the likelihood it will
experience the costs associated with this distress. Direct costs of distress include out-of-pocket cash expenses
that must be paid to third parties (such as lawyers, auditors, consultants and court personnel) in the event of

1 Modigliani, F and Miller, MH. ‘The Cost of Capital, Corporate Finance and the Theory of Investment’, American Economic Review, 48, 1958, pp. 261–97.

in the price they pay for cocoa. Hershey could
be faced with having to increase the price of its
products in response to an increase in the price
of cocoa, whereas the price of Nestlé and Mars

products remains the same. Of course, if the price
of cocoa declines, Hershey would benefit from the
lower price, while Nestlé and Mars are committed
to paying a higher price.

example

Keith Woodward, Vice
President of Finance,
General Mills
‘For General
Mills, hedging and
commodities is core to
our business.’
See the entire interview on
the CourseMate website.

COURSEMATE
SMART VIDEO


Source: Cengage Learning
Free download pdf