The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

106


THE VALUE OF A


PRODUCT COMES


FROM THE EFFORT


NEEDED TO MAKE IT


THE LABOR THEORY OF VALUE


T


he importance of labor in
determining the value of
goods has a history that
can be traced back to the ancient
Greek philosophers. For about 200
years from the mid-17th century, it
dominated economic thought. In
primitive, preindustrial societies
the role of labor in determining the
rate at which one good could
be exchanged for another was fairly
simple. If it took a man a week to
make a fishing net, he was unlikely
to exchange it for a wooden spoon

that had been carved in a morning.
However, the issue became much
more complicated with the
emergence of modern industrial
societies in the 18th century. The
classical economists Adam Smith
(p.61) and David Ricardo (p.84) had
each developed a theory of value
connected to labor, but it was
the German philosopher Karl
Marx (p.105) who set out the most
famous description of the labor
theory of value in his magnum
opus Capital.

Natural resources come
free from nature.

Adding labor to raw
materials creates machines
and commodities.

Adding labor to
natural resources
creates raw materials.

Adding labor to
machines and
commodities creates goods.

The value of a product
comes from the effort
needed to make it.

IN CONTEXT


FOCUS
Theories of value

KEY THINKER
Karl Marx (1818–83)

BEFORE
1662 English economist
William Petty argues that land
is a free gift of nature, and so
all capital is “past labor.”

1690 English philosopher
John Locke argues that
workers deserve the fruits
of their labors.

AFTER
1896 Austrian Economist
Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
publishes Karl Marx and
the Close of his System,
summarizing the criticisms of
Marx’s labor theory of value.

1942 Radical US economist
Paul Sweezy publishes The
Theory of Capitalist
Development, defending
Marx’s labor theory of value.
Free download pdf