The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

128


The assumptions of Marshall’s
model create certain consequences
for firms in perfectly competitive
industries. One of the most
important of these is that firms
have no power over the price that
they can charge. This is because
there are so many firms selling an
identical product that if any one firm
attempts to sell at a price higher
than its competitors, it will sell
nothing. This is virtually guaranteed
because the consumer has perfect
knowledge about the prices being
asked by all firms. In this way the
market price is determined by the
collective interaction of all the firms
and consumers, and each firm has
to accept that one particular price is
the price at which they can sell the
product. They have to “take” the
price, not make it.

Competitive selling
The standard representation of
Marshall’s perfectly competitive
industry (see below) demonstrates
this idea. For instance, at any
moment in time there will be a
world price of wheat—such as $350

per ton—which is determined by
the industry. At this industry price
(shown as a dotted line in the
graph), each farm can sell as much
as it likes, but it will sell nothing at
any price higher than this (because
buyers can go elsewhere). Farms
can choose to sell at a lower price
than other farms if they desire, but
this would be of no advantage to
them—a lower price will not attract
extra demand, because in perfect
competition each farm is a tiny part
of the total world supply (in wheat,
this is around 700 million tons).
By lowering the price, the farm
would merely lower its profits. The
farm has only to decide what output
it needs to produce to maximize
profits. In the case demonstrated by
the graph, it is 3,000 tons, which
the farmer knows can be sold for
$350 per ton.
In this example, the farm is
selling wheat for much more than
the cost of producing it. By selling
3,000 tons at $350 per ton, the
farm’s revenue is $1.05 million; its
costs, however, are $450,000 ($150
× 3,000 tons). The farm’s profit is

THE COMPETITIVE MARKET


In the perfectly competitive industry price
remains the same regardless of any individual firm’s
level of output. A firm will expand production until it
reaches a level beyond which any further production
would cost more than the goods’ selling price.

revenue minus cost—in this case,
$600,000. This is an example of
what classical economists such as
David Ricardo (p.84) describe as
“the market price moving away from
the natural price.” However, in a
perfectly competitive market these
high profits cannot be sustained in
the long term.

Short-term profits
Classical economists such as Smith
and Ricardo were well aware of the
consequences—in competitive
markets—of a price being well
above that required to cover costs.
The high level of profits would act
as an incentive for new firms to
enter the industry. The lack of
barriers to entry in a perfect market
allows any firm to enter the market
easily. In our example it is easy to
imagine farmers switching out of
barley production and into wheat
production if wheat is more
profitable to produce. The impact
of the new entrants would be to
increase total supply, and through
competitive pressure drive the
price downward, so that in a short
time firms would only be able to
make a “normal” level of profit.
This would be when the price just

Average cost
per ton for
firm to supply
product

Price is
determined in
the industry

PROFIT

Cost of
production

Laborers will seek those
employments, and capitalists
those modes of investing their
capital, in which... wages and
profits are highest.
John Elliott Cairnes
Irish economist (1824 –75)

Point at which
increased production
Cost per ton initially would decrease profits
decreases with
economies of scale
0

150

350

0 1,500 3,000

PRICE ($)

OUTPUT OF FIRM (TONS)

COMPANIES


ARE PRICE


TAKERS NOT


PRICE MAKERS


THE COMPETITIVE MARKET

Free download pdf