The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

130


I


n the 19th century a group of
British philosophers known as
the utilitarians introduced the
idea that the happiness of individuals
can be measured and added up,
or aggregated. Italian economist
Vilfredo Pareto disagreed. In his
Manual of Political Economy, he
introduced a weaker definition of
social welfare that has come to

dominate modern economics. His
argument is based on a ranking
of relative happiness known as
“ordinal utility,” rather than an
absolute measurement of happiness
(“cardinal utility”).
Pareto said that individuals
know their own preferences and
will do what suits them best. If
everyone follows their own tastes,

A government wants
to improve the welfare
of its people...

... where each individual
trades to improve their
own welfare...

... but individual welfare
is unmeasurable in absolute
(not relative) terms.

A reasonable aim
would be to reach a state
of Pareto efficiency...

... until they reach a
compromise, or equilibrium, where
you can’t make one person better off
without hurting the others.

MAKE ONE PERSON


BETTER OFF WITHOUT


HURTING THE OTHERS


EFFICIENCY AND FAIRNESS


IN CONTEXT


FOCUS
Welfare economics

KEY THINKER
Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923)

BEFORE
1776 Adam Smith’s The
Wealth of Nations relates
self-interest to social welfare.

1871 British economist
William Jevons says that value
depends entirely on utility.

1874 French economist Léon
Walras uses equations to
determine the overall
equilibrium of an economy.

AFTER
1930–50 John Hicks, Paul
Samuelson, and others use
Pareto optimality as the basis
of modern welfare economics.

1954 US economist Kenneth
Arrow and French economist
Gérard Debreu use
mathematics to show a
connection between free
markets and Pareto optimality.
Free download pdf