The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

212


It was known that a single market
could achieve this balance, or
equilibrium, but it was not clear
that a whole set of markets could
do the same thing.
The problem of “general
equilibrium” was rigorously solved
in 1954 by French mathematician
Gérard Debreu and US economist
Kenneth Arrow (p.209). Applying
advanced mathematics, they
showed that under certain
circumstances a set of markets
could achieve an overall
equilibrium. In a sense Arrow
and Debreu had reworked Adam
Smith’s argument that free
markets would lead to social order.
But Smith made a stronger claim
than the purely factual one that
markets tend toward a point of


stability. He also said that this
equilibrium was desirable
because it entailed a free society.

Pareto-efficient outcomes
Modern economists measure
desirability using a concept known
as “Pareto efficiency” (pp.130–31).
In a Pareto-efficient situation it
is impossible to make one person
better off without making another
person worse off. An improvement
takes place in an economy if goods
change hands in such a way that at
least one person’s welfare increases
and no one else’s falls. Arrow and
Debreu connected market
equilibrium with Pareto efficiency.
In doing so they rigorously probed
Smith’s ultimate contention that
market outcomes are good. They

MARKETS AND SOCIAL OUTCOMES


An Edgeworth box is a way of showing the distribution of goods in an
economy. In this example the economy contains two people—Ben and Sarah
—and two goods—20 apples and 10 pears. Each point in the box represents a
possible distribution of apples and pears between Ben and Sarah. The yellow
line is the contract curve, which represents the possible allocation of goods
that could be reached by Ben and Sarah after trading with each other.
Trading to points on this curve leads to Pareto efficiency.


did this by proving two theorems,
known as the “fundamental
theorems of welfare economics.”
The first welfare theorem holds
that any pure free market economy
in equilibrium is necessarily
“Pareto efficient”—that it leads to a
distribution of resources in which
it is impossible to make someone
better off without making someone
else worse off. Individuals begin
with an “endowment” of goods.
They trade with each other and
reach an equilibrium, which the
theorem holds will be efficient.
Pareto efficiency is a weak
ethical criterion. A situation in
which one rich person has all of a
desired good and eveyone else has
none of it would be Pareto efficient
because it would be impossible to
remove some of the good from the
rich person without making him
worse off. So this first welfare
theorem says that markets are
efficient but says nothing about
the critical issue of distribution.
The second welfare theorem
deals with this problem. In an
economy there are typically many
Pareto-efficient allocations of
resources. Some will be fairly equal
distributions, some highly unequal.

How this coordination
[of supply and demand]
takes place has been a
central preoccupation
of economic theory since
Adam Smith.
Kenneth Arrow

BEN’S APPLES

Contract
curve

SARAH’S APPLES

SARAH’S PEARS

BEN’S PEARS Ben (10 apples, 5 pears)
Sarah (10 apples, 5 pears)

Ben (6 apples, 2 pears)
Sarah (14 apples, 8 pears)

Ben (15 apples, 9 pears)
Sarah (5 apples, 1 pear)

0

2

4 6

6 4

8

10

8

10

2

0 5 10 15 20

(^20151050)
0

Free download pdf