The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

246


market are rational, they do not
simply guess at future prices by
looking at previous ones. Instead,
they will attempt to forecast
future prices based on the
information available and—
critically—using a correct model
of the economy. They will make
educated predictions rather than
blindly following past behavior.
They will do this because if they
do not form their expectations
rationally, they will be punished
by the market and lose money.
We use rational expectations
all the time. Farmers, for instance,
make decisions about what to
plant based on past prices, current
conditions, and future probabilities.
They do not assume that if they
grow the same amount of the same
commodity they did five years
earlier, it will achieve the same
market price now—and neither do
the commodity dealers trading in
agricultural goods. Punishment
from the market forces people to
behave rationally and, over time,
their expectations can be assumed
to be as good as the best available
economic model. The theory of
rational expectations is deceptively


simple but has startling
consequences. Under adaptive
expectations government
intervention might work
temporarily because it could take
people by surprise. They would
not anticipate future government
policies and so an unexpected
expansion of spending would
act like a positive “shock” in
the economy, with short-term
real effects. Even these temporary
effects are impossible under the
theory of rational expectations
since people’s forecasts for price
increases adjust immediately.

Anticipating events
In 1975, two US economists,
Thomas Sargent and Neil Wallace,
claimed that if expectations are
rational, not only would individuals
begin to expect government
intervention, but they would
adjust their behavior in such
a way that policy would be
rendered ineffective. Assuming
rational expectations, people
would know that the government
had an incentive to generate
shocks, such as trying to keep
down unemployment. They

RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS


would adjust their expectations
accordingly. For example,
individuals would understand that
when a government attempts to
use monetary policy (such as
cutting interest rates) to maintain
employment, it leads to higher
inflation. People therefore alter
their expectations of wage and
price increases accordingly.
Instead of feeling wealthier, their
expectation of inflation cancels out
the effects of lower rates of interest
looked for by the government. In
this way monetary policy becomes
completely ineffective because
it will always be accounted for,
and people’s changed behavior
will undo it.
Policy makers had previously
believed that there was a trade-
off between unemployment and
inflation—that governments
could boost the economy and
achieve higher employment in
the long run with higher inflation
(pp.202–03). Under rational
expectations, this trade-off
dissolves. Unemployment is
determined by the productive
capacities of the economy: the
productivity and technological
capacities of its firms and
the efficiency of its markets.
Policy makers cannot boost
the economy beyond this level
of employment.

The Lucas critique
US economist Robert Lucas
pointed out that if individuals’
expectations do adjust with
policy, this means that the
whole structure of the economy—
the sets of relationships
between different households,
firms, and the government—
alters with changes in policy.
As a result the effects of
policy are not always those
that are intended.

It is rather surprising that
expectations have not
previously been regarded
as rational dynamic models,
since rationality is assumed
in all other aspects of
entrepreneurial behavior.
John Muth

A farmer in Australia inspects his
crop. Farmers do not decide what to
plant based solely on the past. They
also weigh factors such as the
weather and levels of demand.

Free download pdf