278
THE ECONOMY IS
CHAOTIC EVEN WHEN
INDIVIDUALS ARE NOT
COMPLEXITY AND CHAOS
N
o system yet discovered
guarantees a good return
in the stock market. One
might have hoped that economics,
with its theoretical models in which
the economy always reverts to an
equilibrium, would give us such a
tool. Most economic theory is
modeled on the laws of motion
developed in the 1680s: every
action leads to an outcome, and
every event is linked in a causal
chain backward and forward in
time in what is called a “linear”
process. Standard economics
builds its large-scale predictions—
the equilibrium that an economy
will arrive at—from the combined
effect of the behavior of rational
individuals reacting to prices.
Looking for complexity
If the real world does indeed
behave like this, why do we find it
so hard to predict stock market
crashes? Some economists feel
the entire linear approach is
obsolete. Austrian economist
Friedrich Hayek (p.177) believed
that economics is far too complex
to model in the same way as
physics. One response to such
doubts is complexity theory,
which emerged from the work
on thermodynamics of Russian-
Belgian chemist Ilya Prigogine
(1917–2003). Unlike standard
economics, this approach
recognizes that predictable,
regular actions by individuals
do not necessarily lead to a
stable, predictable economy.
In 1975, French economists
Jean-Michel Grandmont and Alan
Kirman argued that economies are
“complex systems.” In standard
economic models of perfect
competition individuals do not
Tiny changes in initial conditions can
cause large changes in outcomes. This
is known as the “butterfly effect:”
Edward Lorenz’s suggestion that a
butterfly flapping its wings in Brazil
could lead to a cyclone in Texas.
IN CONTEXT
FOCUS
The macroeconomy
KEY THINKERS
René Thom (1923–2002)
Jean-Michel Grandmont
(1939 – )
Alan Kirman (1939 – )
BEFORE
1887 French mathematician
Henri Poincaré’s analysis
of the interaction between
three bodies orbiting each
other lays the foundation
for chaos theory.
1950s French mathematician
Benoît Mandelbrot finds
recurring patterns in the
variation of cotton prices.
1960 US mathematician and
meteorologist Edward Lorenz
discovers the butterfly effect
in meteorology.
AFTER
1980s Northern Irish
economist Brian Arthur
develops complexity theory.