320 BANK RUNS
In September, 2007, the first
serious British bank run
since 1866 took place. Northern
Rock, Britain’s eighth-largest
bank, was a fast-growing
mortgage lender. To expand
its business, it had become
over-reliant on “wholesale”
funding—funding provided
by other institutions—rather
than personal deposits. When
wholesale financial markets
froze on August 9, 2007, a
gradual, unseen wholesale
A modern bank run
run began. At 8:30 p.m. on
Thursday, September 13, BBC
Television News reported that
the UK central bank, the Bank
of England, would announce
emergency liquidity support
the next day.
It emerged later that Mervyn
King, the Governor of the Bank
of England, had opposed a
rescue offer by Lloyds, another
British bank. King had
suggested that central bank
support might reassure
depositors. However, this
reassurance did not happen,
and a run on personal deposits
began over the internet that
evening. Under Britain’s deposit
insurance program, deposits
above $3,300 (£2,000) were not
fully insured, and the next day,
long lines formed outside
Northern Rock branches. The
run ended the following
Monday evening after the
government announced a
guarantee for all deposits.
Diamond and Dybvig showed that
this property also makes the bank
vulnerable to a run. A run occurs
when, on Tuesday, patient people
become pessimistic about what
they will receive from the bank on
Wednesday, and so withdraw their
deposits on Tuesday. Their actions
mean that the bank must sell
investments at a loss; it will not
have the resources to pay all of its
patient and impatient customers,
and those later in the line will not
receive anything. Knowing this,
customers become eager to be at
the front of the line.
Pessimism can arise out of
concerns about investments, other
people’s withdrawals, or the bank’s
survival. Crucially, this allows for
the possibility of a self-fulfilling
bank run even if the bank is sound.
For instance, suppose that on
Tuesday I believe that other people
are going to withdraw their
deposits—I then decide to do so as
well because I fear that the bank
may fail. Then suppose that many
other people think in the same way
that I have. This itself can cause
a run on the bank, even if the bank
would otherwise be able to meet its
obligations today and tomorrow.
This is an example of what
economists call “multiple
equilibrims”—more than one
outcome. Here there are two
outcomes: a “good” one in which the
bank survives and a “bad” one in
which it is sunk by a run. Where we
end up may depend on the people’s
beliefs and expectations rather than
the true health of the bank.
Preventing bank runs
Diamond and Dybvig showed how
governments could alleviate the
problem of bank runs. Their model
was partly a defense of the US’s
system of federal deposit insurance,
under which the state guarantees
the value of all bank deposits up
to a specified amount. Introduced
in 1933, this system reduced bank
failures. In March, 1933, President
Franklin D. Roosevelt also declared
A panicking crowd is held back
by police outside a German bank
in 1914. The declaration of war had
caused pessimism among savers,
leading to a number of bank runs.