The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

CONTEMPORARY ECONOMICS 321


In 1933, President Roosevelt
signed an act that guaranteed bank
deposits. Bank runs were reduced,
but some believe that such deposit
guarantees increase risk taking.

By the afternoon of
March 3, scarcely a bank
in the country was
open to do business.
Franklin D. Roosevelt

In the history of modern
capitalism, crises are the
norm, not the exception.
Nouriel Roubini
Stephen Mihm

a national bank holiday to prevent
people from withdrawing their
savings. Alternatively, the central
bank can act as the “lender of last
resort” to banks. However, there is
often uncertainty about what the
central bank will do. Deposit
insurance is ideal, because it
ensures that patient people will
not participate in a bank run.


Alternative views
There are alternative explanations
for the existence of banks. Some
focus on banks’ investment role.
The bank can gather and keep
private information about
investments, choosing between
good and bad investments, and
reflect this private information
efficiently through the returns it
offers to savers. It can offer a
return to depositors that is only
possible if it carries out its
monitoring role well.
In 1991, US economists Charles
Calomiris and Charles Kahn
published an article that took issue
with the Diamond–Dybvig view.
They argued that bank runs are
good for banks. In the absence of
deposit insurance, depositors have
an incentive to keep a close eye on
how well their bank performs. The


threat of a run also provides an
incentive to the bank to make safe
investments. This is one side of
so-called “moral hazard” (pp.208–
09). The other side is that managers
will take riskier decisions than they
would if there were no deposit
insurance. The problem of moral
hazard became apparent in the
1980s US savings and loan crisis,
when mortgage lenders were
allowed to make riskier loans and
deposit insurance was enhanced.
US bank failures rose.

Recent crises
It is hard to prove which of these
two views about bank runs is
correct, since in practice neither
explanation can be isolated. There
are many forms of moral hazard in a
bank. A shareholder may encourage
risk taking because all he can
lose is his investment. A bank
employee, offered bonus incentives,
may take risks because all that is
at stake is a job. One commonly
proposed solution to moral hazard
is tougher regulation.

Recent bank crises have usually
begun with investment losses.
Banks are forced to sell assets to
reduce their borrowing. This leads
to further falls in asset prices and
further losses. A run on deposits
follows, which can spread to other
banks to become a panic. If the
whole banking system is affected,
it is called a systemic banking
crisis. In the 2007–08 crisis, runs
occurred despite the system of
deposit insurance. A large part
of the recent crisis took place
institutions that are not regulated
as banks, such as hedge funds, but
were doing much the same as a
bank: borrowing for short terms
and lending for long terms.
Many countries strengthened
their deposit insurance policies
during the financial crisis that
began in 2007–08. This is
understandable, since bank failures
can have a devastating effect on
the real economy, breaking the
connection between people with
savings and people who need to
invest. The moral hazard argument
is like fire prevention, in that it is
concerned with protecting the
economy from a future crisis.
However, the midst of a crisis may
not be the time to be talking about
preventative actions. ■
Free download pdf