The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

97


Whatever renders a
larger capital necessary
in any trade or business,
limits the competition
in that business.
John Stuart Mill

INDUSTRIAL AND ECONOMIC REVOLUTIONS


does not matter if there is a monopoly
as long as there are no barriers to
entering and exiting the market—
the mere threat of competition
means that the monopoly will set
the price at a competitive level.
This is because a higher price
might attract new entrants to the
market, who would take market
share from the monopoly. For this
reason prices may be no higher
under a monopoly than in a market
with many competing firms.


Natural monopolies
One argument that began to take
shape during Marshall’s lifetime is
that some monopolies are “natural”
because of the enormous cost
advantages of having a single firm.
Many public utilities are natural
monopolies, including telephone
networks, gas, and water. The
fixed cost of setting up a network
of gas distribution pipes is huge,
compared to the cost of pumping
an extra amount of gas.


This idea led to an acceptance
of national monopolies in the
public utilities in many countries.
Even so, governments began to
intervene in these markets to
counteract the possible monopoly
effects. The problem is that in the
case of a natural monopoly,
the fixed costs are so high that
compelling the firm to charge a
competitive price might make the
firm unprofitable. Solutions to this
problem include the wholesale
nationalization of industries or
the establishment of regulatory
organizations that place limits
on price increases, helping
consumers but also ensuring the
economic viability of the industry.
Mainstream economists argue
that monopolized markets fall short
of the perfectly competitive ideal.
This view has led to government
anti-trust policies, which seek
to move markets toward
competitiveness. This has meant
the introduction of measures aimed
at preventing monopolies from
abusing their market power,
including the breakup of monopolies
and the banning of mergers of firms
that would create monopolies.
The modern Austrian School,
including US economist Thomas
DiLorenzo (1954– ), are critical of
this approach. Both argue that real
market competition is not the
passive behavior of perfectly
competitive firms operating in a
state of equilibrium. It is about
cut-throat rivalry between an often
small number of large businesses.
Competition takes place through
price and non-price competition,

through advertising and marketing,
and through large firms innovating
and creating new products.
Slightly apart from this school
of economists, Austrian economist
Joseph Schumpeter (p.149) also
stressed the dynamic potential
of monopoly as firms compete to
create new products and dominate
entire markets because of the
potential profits. What economists
agree on is that true competition
is good for consumers. It is less
certain whether or not monopoly is
incompatible with this. In the early
20th century German economist
Robert Liefman claimed that
“only a peculiar combination of
competition and monopoly brings
about the greatest possible
satisfaction of wants.” ■

In 1998, the US pharmaceutical
industry asserted its monopoly on
an AIDS drug by taking legal action
against the South African government,
which had been buying cheaper,
generic versions of the drug.

Operators work the switchboards of
the AT&T company in New York in the
1940s. Because of the company’s size
and dominance, it was considered to
be a natural monopoly.

Free download pdf