The Ancient Greek Economy. Markets, Households and City-States

(Rick Simeone) #1

THE LEGAL FOUNDATIONS OF ECONOMIC GROwTH 127


The description of the property can be as brief as one word (‘house’ [οἰκία] or


‘field’ [χωρίον]). In some cases, however, one finds more details such as infor-


mation about roof tiles, towers, doors, viaducts, gardens and enclosures.^72 The


purchase prices indicate that it was not only the wealthy who registered the


sales of their property. The prices range from a low of 60 dr. (#29) to a high


of 8,000 dr. (#40). There are forty amounts preserved out of the forty-seven


sales that were originally on the stone. One out of five are 300 dr. or less. Over


a third fall below 500 dr., and over half fall below 1,000 dr., prices that would


have been affordable by citizens with modest resources (see Appendix III).


There is no registration fee given for each of the sales as there is in the poletai


documents at Athens, but if there was one, it could not have been very high


for it did not discourage those with small amounts of property from register-


ing their sales. The inscription also reveals that property was not circulating


within a small group of neighbors and kin. The tribal affiliations recorded for


the buyer and seller appear to denote geographical regions.^73 In thirty-eight


cases these affiliations are preserved for both parties, and in the overwhelming


majority of cases, thirty-one, the buyer and seller come from different regions.


Once again we find that the existence of written records helps to reduce the


asymmetry of information that would otherwise have discouraged transactions


between parties from different areas (for asymmetry of information in transac-


tions concerning amphoras, see Lawall, Chapter 11 of this volume). Finally, it


has been noted that some of the sales are actually the repayment of loans made


on the security of property.^74 The amounts in these transactions range from a


high of 5,000 dr. (#39) to a low of 100 dr. (#30), which suggests that credit in


the form of secured loans was available to the wealthy and to those of modest


means alike.


Athens and Tenos were not unusual in maintaining records about sales of

property. A papyrus dated to the third century BCE collects several laws from


Ptolemaic Alexandria and provides rules about registering sales. The treasurers


are to record the names of sellers and buyers with their patronymics and demes,


the date of the transaction, and the location of the property. As several scholars


have noted, the type of information recorded in these documents is very sim-


ilar to that found in the records of sales from Tenos. The registration fee is not


preserved but appears to have been low, possibly only 5 percent.^75 There is also


evidence for similar types of records in Miletus, Samos, Camarina and possibly


several cities in Northern Greece.^76 The practice was clearly widespread. In


Roman Egypt there was a central register called the bibliotheke kteseon.^77 These


records may have helped officials in levying taxes, but the primary aim of the


edict is to prevent fraud through ignorance (ἵνα οἱ συναλλάσσοντες μὴ κατ‘


ἄγνοιαν ἐνεδρεύωνται) or to reduce ‘asymmetry of information.’ These records


share the same deficiencies as those from the Greek world: they only give the


names of neighbors but do not indicate where the precise boundary lay.

Free download pdf