The Ancient Greek Economy. Markets, Households and City-States

(Rick Simeone) #1

INDUSTRY STRUCTURE AND INCOME OPPORTUNITIES 151


people in the way that other aspects of Athenian life appear to have been. Even


Glotz believed that ‘the head of an undertaking was not driven by the need


to collect as much capital and labour as possible because he was not driven by


the necessity of getting the biggest possible returns out of expensive machines,


in order to diminish his general costs and to obtain a progressive increase in


profits.’^16 Hopper observed that factories were acquired by chance as a result


of other financial dealings, and that there is no evidence of investments made


to extend an enterprise, nor of any particular expertise or enthusiasm for effi-


ciency on the part of owners, although he does not explain this peculiar insou-


ciance.^17 Finley mocked Demosthenes for not having taken depreciation into


account in his description of returns on his investment in manufacturing;^18 a


more charitable interpretation would take returns on manufacturing invest-


ment about 20 percent higher than on land to imply that investors did account


for depreciation (and some other costs) – at least implicitly. Humphreys speaks


of ‘small-scale, disconnected business ventures, assessed by the security of their


returns rather than their potentiality for expansion’ and attributes this largely


to the social preferences of Athenians, who were happier being rentiers rather


than serious industrialists.^19 Of course they were happier being rentiers – that


is how the apophora system worked;^20 it does not mean that the slaves and


freedmen (who actually ran their businesses) were not interested in profit.


Even in the 2007 Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, several


contributions start by noting the apparent failure of the ancients to build large


manufacturing enterprises.^21 The analysis undertaken in this chapter demon-


strates that firm size was quite varied and followed patterns predictable from


modern business theory. It appears that ancient Athenian manufacturers devel-


oped and grew their businesses in much the same way we would have done,


given the level of available technology.


There were a number of large manufacturing enterprises in Athens. Lysias

and Polemarchus claimed to have co-owned 120 slaves, most of whom must


have been employed in their shield factory (Lys. 12.19). This figure might be


exaggerated but must have seemed plausible to the judges presiding over the


case, and even if we halve the number, it remains a large factory.^22 We hear of


another shield factory some twenty years later (or possibly the same one under


new ownership), whose revenues imply at least sixty-five slaves.^23 In his speech


against his guardian Aphobus, Demosthenes claimed that one of the work-


shops he inherited employed “thirty-two or thirty-three slaves and the other,


twenty” (Dem. 27.9). Pantaenetos seems to have employed about thirty slaves


in processing ore (Dem. 37.4, 17, 31). Aristophanes’ portrayal of Cleon, espe-


cially in the Knights, is generally taken to mean that he inherited a tannery, or


at least funds that a forebear had made from tanning; if so his wealth suggests


it was a large enterprise.^24 There is reason to believe that Anytus, rich enough


to have been accused of bribing a panel of judges, might have owed his wealth

Free download pdf