The Ancient Greek Economy. Markets, Households and City-States

(Rick Simeone) #1

AEGEAN-LEVANTINE TRADE, 600–300 BCE 293


Oration (2.38), he notes that ‘on account of the greatness of the city everything


comes in from all the world, and for us it is as natural to enjoy the goods of


others as it is to enjoy our own local produce.’ Similar links between Athenian


power and pleasure in imports are expressed by the Old Oligarch (2.7): ‘it is


because of their mastery of the sea that the Athenians have mixed with var-


ious peoples in different areas and discovered a range of festive practices. In


consequence, what is sweet in Sicily, Italy, Cyprus, Egypt, Lydia, Pontus, the


Peloponnese or elsewhere has all been brought together in one place because


of the mastery of the sea.’ Athens in the 430s and 420s was a major entrepôt,


and the range of commodities found there must have been extensive, but how


much more extensive than other equally important entrepôts, like Syracuse or


Carthage, is open to question. The Atheno-centric view of both Pericles and


the Oligarch serve rhetorical purposes and obscure the fact that the Athenians,


like many others elsewhere, were experiencing the benefits of a process that


had begun before their empire coalesced and would continue after its collapse.


There was, in general circulation all over the Mediterranean, an abundance of


goods, and while some markets might have been better stocked than others,


only the poorest and most remote likely had no experience of at least some


small imports and foreign commodities. Both passages also strongly imply that


it was not just the wealthy elites, those with plenty of spare tetradrachmas, who


enjoyed these imports, but anyone with even a few hemiobols to spend who


strolled the agora.^36


Some years ago, Braund ( 1994 ) took issue with the implication of mass access

to luxury goods found in these passages, arguing that most ‘luxury’ imports


would still be well beyond the financial reach of the mass of poor Athenians,


and that the picture of a shopping utopia painted by Pericles was little more


than an ‘Athenian mirage,’ a political panacea. While Braund is certainly cor-


rect to draw attention to the political messages of these passages, still we should


question whether his view of mass access is correct.^37 There will always be


goods occupying the highest luxury register, that are indeed well beyond the


reach of the ‘average consumer’; such goods are designed to be that way, serv-


ing primarily as tools of elite social distancing: today’s Bentley coupe, Prada


shoes, and Tiffany jewelry are cases in point. But not all imports, even those


Braund considered luxury goods, like those listed in the Hermippus fragment


noted earlier, were necessarily of the highest luxury register. Like the com-


modity state, the luxury register is dynamic, with items moving into and out


of it depending on the immediate context. In late fifth century Athens, and no


doubt elsewhere, a number of political, economic, and social forces converged


that might have caused some of these imports to trickle down out of the


higher registers, if in fact they ever occupied them to begin with.^38 Included


among these converging forces was the Athenian sense of egalitarianism that


generally discouraged the wealthy and other elites from engaging in displays

Free download pdf