The Ancient Greek Economy. Markets, Households and City-States

(Rick Simeone) #1

INTRODUCTION 19


In the Ancient Greek world there was nothing like the large loans made by


French banks to Imperial Russia for the construction of railroads at the end


of the nineteenth century. Nevertheless, markets for credit did exist, albeit on


a more modest level.


Markets, Commodities and Household Demand


Let us sum up so far. Most cities had a permanent central agora; in large cit-


ies this might be subdivided into different sections, and smaller (and perhaps


occasional) markets might be found in the countryside if its chora were exten-


sive. Periodic markets and panegyreis supplemented permanent markets in most


regions, and markets brought together both local produce as well as that of


other regions. The forces of demand and supply shaped the prices of goods and


services and set the basic parameters of interest rates.


That much is clear from the evidence discussed earlier in this chapter. But

markets of this size and distribution can only exist and develop in a society


that exerts high enough levels of demand for the sorts of goods retailed in


marketplaces. On the traditional view of the economy (and one which still


has many adherents), most households were self-sufficient, aiming to satisfy


their own subsistence needs but little else. According to von Reden, the effect


of expanding needs – that is, demand – on the operation of interdependent


market-exchange was limited: ‘In no case can it be shown that it was regular,


widespread, or sustained enough to be supplied effectively by the market with-


out state interference.’^96 In other words, levels of demand were generally low,


higher levels of demand being irregular at best, and market forces by them-


selves were insufficient to guarantee supply. But does this view really reflect the


evidence we have for household requirements in the Greek world?


Attica provides us with the largest body of evidence for discussion. Few

would dissent from the view that wealthy oikoi not only created demand for a


wide variety of commodities but produced surpluses well in excess of domes-


tic needs. Good evidence for the higher income-tier households can be found


in the Attic Stelai (IG I^3 421–430), a series of fragmentary inscriptions record-


ing the auctioned household contents belonging to a variety of individuals


who were convicted following the mutilation of the herms and the parody of


the Eleusinian Mysteries in 415 BCE.^97 These records show the large stockpiles


of goods in wealthy households, particularly ceramic goods and textiles, but


also furniture, slaves, tools, livestock, building materials, weapons and other


miscellaneous items. These men were clearly avid consumers of goods bought


from markets. And they produced for the market as well: one of the most nota-


ble resources in the Stelai is the farm of Adeimantus on Thasos (IG i^3 426, lines


44–51; cf. Dem. 42.20, 24) which specialized in wine production and, when


confiscated, had some 6,000 litres of wine in store, clearly more than the most

Free download pdf