The Ancient Greek Economy. Markets, Households and City-States

(Rick Simeone) #1

AChAEMENID ANATOLIA AND ThE SLAVE SUPPLY 325


auctioned off slaves confiscated by the state in a similar manner.^52 That is a


minimal picture, and we should not rule out the possibility of auctions at mar-


kets such as Sounion adjacent to the mining district. Slave sales in Athens were


warranted by law to prevent sharp practice and many were recorded to aid


proof of title.^53 In other words, we are looking at a process that was in no way


haphazard, but regular, organised and subject to the laws (and taxes) of the polis.


It has already been noted that slaves were sold for comparatively low amounts

in Athens. The implications of this fact are significant: low slave prices relative


to wages enabled the option of slave ownership to trickle much further down


the wealth spectrum in Classical Athens than was the case in other well-known


slave societies such as Imperial Rome or the U.S. South. Our price data dove-


tail well with our information on the distribution of slave ownership from lit-


erary and epigraphic texts. Although Attic texts note disparity in slaveholdings


between rich and poor (e.g., Ar. Eccl. 593), this was much less pronounced than


in Rome. The normative upper ceiling lies at around fifty slaves; few individu-


als could have owned more than this number. But only the poorer elements


of the free population will have not owned any slaves.^54 This pattern of slave


ownership fundamentally shaped the Athenian economy; the most obvious


explanation is that it was a function of the low prices of slaves, which resulted


in turn from a well-organised system of supply and low transport costs. That


this supply was clearly capable of meeting high levels of demand is evident


in contemporary literature. For example, Xenophon’s plans outlined in the


Poroi to revitalise public finances in the 350s presuppose the availability of slave


labour on a large scale – to the extent that within several years the state could


buy 10,000 slaves for the mines, and buy them cheaply: his computations are


based on a price of around 180 drachmas per slave.^55 Such proposals only make


sense against the backdrop of a well-organised and abundant supply of cheap


slaves, and do not add up if we suppose that the slave supply was dependent on


the staccato injections of bodies into the market implied by any model based


largely on warfare and predation by Greeks against non-Greeks. To understand


the economic opportunities of which Athenians took advantage by tapping


into this source of external supply, it is worth contrasting Attica’s slave system


with a neighbouring slave system which did not engage with foreign markets


to any appreciable degree: Sparta.


The Athenian and Spartan Slave Populations: Relative


Strategies of Supply


Let us begin by debunking a popular myth: that the Spartan helots were serfs,


public slaves, a mixture of the two, or held some mystery status located in the


murky area ‘between slavery and freedom.’ Ducat convincingly argued that the


helots, at least during our period, were privately owned slaves, and Luraghi has

Free download pdf