The Ancient Greek Economy. Markets, Households and City-States

(Rick Simeone) #1

AChAEMENID ANATOLIA AND ThE SLAVE SUPPLY 329


they were destined. There was no need to foster the slave family as a social


institution: permission to marry or set up house with another slave could, of


course, be granted as an incentive for hard work (Xen. Oec. 9.5), and we must


reckon with the impulse of most slaves themselves to achieve something of this


sort. But it is unlikely that marriage and family was the standard fate of most


Athenian slaves, for the slave population seems to have maintained its ‘barbar-


ian’ character over time, and there was no wider need to foster slave families


due to labor requirements.^70 At Sparta, the situation was completely different.


Slave families were the prime institution underpinning the labor supply, which


necessitated a completely different approach to the utilization of slave labor.


Access to a reliable slave supply gave Athenian slave-owners flexibility and

volume in their labor needs. Not only could slaves be employed in a diverse


range of tasks regardless of whether these tasks were favourable or not to pop-


ulation reproduction, but access to foreign supply provided choice of skills and


scope for expansion. Take, for instance, the Athenian liturgical class. Many of


the key sources of wealth for this class were dominated by slave labour, from


agricultural production to craft workshops and mining. For an entrepreneur-


ial Athenian setting up a craft workshop or mining concession and aiming to


maximize his profits, labour supply was a key variable.^71 Because Athens was


connected to extensive inter-regional markets via maritime routes, its econ-


omy was effectively plugged-in to levels of demand that well exceeded domes-


tic requirements. This meant that ventures such as craft workshops were able to


expand in terms of individual size and aggregate number to meet this demand.


If labour supply were restricted, this would have imposed a ceiling on effective


expansion, but with a supply of foreign labour that was abundant and flexible,


workshop owners were not encumbered with such restraints and could poten-


tially expand their operations within the limits imposed by technology and


basic organisational structures (see Chapter 6). Fine-pottery production is one


obvious example:  Athens had been producing fine wares for both domestic


and foreign markets well before the advent of the Classical period. Or take the


production of objects such as shields: the aspidopegeion (shield factory) owned


by Lysias and Polemarchus must have employed close to 100 slaves (Lys. 12.19),


and Pasion’s shield factory perhaps 60–70 (Dem. 36.11).^72 It is clear that these


establishments were not producing to meet piecemeal local orders but were


churning out large numbers of shields that could be sold in foreign markets.^73


Here we can see how the slave supply, whose tendrils reached into the interior


of Thrace, Anatolia and beyond, interlocked with Athens’ export trade in man-


ufactured goods and silver. The latter simply could not have existed without


the former; nor could it have expanded as it did on a home-grown helot-style


population: cheap imported labour from Phrygia, Paphlagonia, Caria, Thrace


and a range of other regions was the essential ingredient.^74

Free download pdf