The Ancient Greek Economy. Markets, Households and City-States

(Rick Simeone) #1

ARISTOTLE AND FOREIGN TRADE 49


of it, it does not have the consent of the ruler of the sea? And yet it is
from these very materials that I get my ships, taking timber from one
place, iron from another. Furthermore they will prevent any of our
rivals from transporting these materials as a cargo to any other place,
with the threat that, otherwise, they will be stopped from using the sea
at all? Thus, despite producing nothing from my land, I possess all these
materials because of the sea. Yet no other city has two of these things.
Timber and flax are not found in the same city; rather, where there is
an abundance of flax, the land is flat and timberless. Copper and iron do
not come from the same city either, nor is there any other combination
of two or three of the materials to be found in any one city, but, rather,
there is just one in this place, another in that.^37

The tone is different from that of Aristotle. The examples are more numerous


and more specific (Aristotle does not go beyond trophe). Above all, it is not


a question of surplus (cf. πλεονάζω, Pol. 7.6.4), but rather of ‘wealth’ (use of


πλουτέω) derived from such and such a commodity. The highly original and


perceptive character of the Old Oligarch’s work is evident in its analysis of


economics as well as in that of politics. In Aristotle, foreign trade is viewed, as


with all other aspects of the city, from the perspective of a vision of how life


ought to be. Here we have a vision freed from the ideological baggage of a


normative approach, one that is therefore much closer to reality, to the actual


interplay of interests set in motion by foreign trade regardless of the ideology


(naturally quite varied) of those involved in this activity.


But it is perhaps in a place where we would least expect it, in the writings

of Plato, that one actually finds the most original point of view. In the Republic,


Socrates sets himself the task of examining the city. He explains its origins,


based on an association of partners, who are linked together by the fact that


each one needs (χρεία) the others. The division of labor within the city allows


everyone to save time while at the same time ensuring the manufacture of


goods of the highest quality.^38 At this point another problem arises – the ques-


tion of foreign trade:


‘And there is another thing,’ I said. ‘It would be almost impossible to build
the state itself in the sort of place where there is no call for imported
goods.’
‘Yes, impossible.’
‘Then we shall need yet other things that we lack which will be brought
in from another state.’
‘We shall.’
‘And there again if the supplier arrives empty handed without bringing
any of the things which are needed by those people who are supplying
what his people need, he will go away empty handed, won’t he?’
‘I should think so.’
Free download pdf