The most obvious and serious market imperfection has been the different tax treatment of divi-
dends and capital gains. U.S. tax rates on dividends have in the past been much higher than on
capital gains. By 2014, the tax rate on both dividends and capital gains was 23.8%, although the
effective tax rate on capital gains was lower because payment can be deferred until shares are sold.
Thus taxes have favored repurchases.
Taxes alone cannot explain payout policy, however. For example, corporations paid out massive
sums in cash dividends even in the 1960s, 1970s, and early 1980s, when the top income-tax rate on
dividends was 70% or more.
Of course some investors—widows and orphans, for example—may depend on regular cash
dividends. But the supply of dividends should expand to satisfy this clientele, and if the supply of
dividends already meets demand, then no single firm can increase its market value simply by pay-
ing dividends. (A dividend announcement may be good news for investors, but that news would
come out sooner or later through other channels.)
It is difficult to be dogmatic about payout. But remember, if investment and capital-structure
decisions are held constant, then arguments about payout policy are largely about shuffling money
from one pocket to another. Unless large tax consequences accompany these shuffles, it’s unlikely
that firm value is much affected by the choice between dividends and repurchases. The short-run
choice is tactical. Longer-run payout strategy depends on the life cycle of the firm from youth and
growth to profitable maturity.
Investors seem interested in payout mostly because of the information they read into payout
decisions. Investors also push mature firms to pay out cash. Committing to a regular cash dividend
is a particularly effective signal of financial discipline.
For comprehensive reviews of the literature on payout policy, see:
F. Allen and R. Michaely, “Payout Policy,” in G. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R. Stulz, (eds.), Hand-
book of the Economics of Finance: Corporate Finance (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 2003).
H. DeAngelo, L. DeAngelo, and D. Skinner, “Corporate Payout Policy,” Foundations and Trends in
Finance 3 (2008), pp. 95–287.
J. Farre-Mensa, R. Michaely, and M. Schmalz, “Payout Policy,” in A. Lo and R. Merton (eds.), Annual
Review of Financial Economics 6 (December 2014), pp. 75–134.
For a survey of managers’ attitudes to the payout decision, see:
A. Kalay and M. Lemmon, “Payout Policy,” in B. E. Eckbo (ed.), Handbook of Empirical Corporate
Finance (Amsterdam: Elsevier/North-Holland, 2007), Chapter 10.
A. Brav, J. R. Graham, C. R. Harvey, and R. Michaely, “Payout Policy in the 21st Century,” Journal of
Financial Economics 77 (September 2005), pp. 483–527.
● ● ● ● ●
FURTHER
READING
Select problems are available in McGraw-Hill’s Connect.
Please see the preface for more information.
BASIC
- Dividend payments In 2014, Entergy paid a regular quarterly dividend of $.83 per share.
a. Match each of the following dates.
(A1) Friday, July 25 (B1) Record date
(A2) Monday, August 11 (B2) Payment date
(A3) Tuesday, August 12 (B3) Ex-dividend date
(A4) Thursday, August 14 (B4) Last with-dividend date
(A5) Tuesday, September 2 (B5) Declaration date
● ● ● ● ●
PROBLEM
SETS
430 Part Five Payout Policy and Capital Structure
bre44380_ch16_410-435.indd 430 10/05/15 01:41 PM