Monday9 March 2020 ★ FINANCIAL TIMES 17
W
e are on the cusp of
another economic pol-
icy error in the euro-
zone. Its roots lie in a
mixture of compla-
cency aboutcoronavirus nd a deep-a
seated beliefthat monetary policy has
no ammunition left when interest rates
are negative and that fiscal policy is, by
nature, constrained.
It is comical, yet consistent with the
observation above, to hear European
policymakers reiterating that they are
waiting and monitoring the situation.
Eurozone finance ministers could not
agree on a co-ordinated policy response
when they held a telephone conference
last week. And theG7 industrialised
nations nly managed to agree — guesso
what — to monitor the situation. Even
income currently subsidises research.
The biggest change is to recognise that
employers, who benefit directly from a
highly educated workforce, should con-
tribute to the higher education costs of
the graduates they employ — govern-
ments already contribute because soci-
ety benefits and individual students
contribute because they benefit person-
ally. This third contribution would
strengthen collaboration between
employers and universities.
The principle of employer contribu-
tions already exists, for example
through theapprenticeship levy, sup-
port for work-based degree courses and
some bursaries. But the existing
arrangements are incoherent, insub-
stantial and often ineffective.Ministers
could decide to set employers’ national
insurance contributions at a higher rate
for university graduates and direct the
revenue to universities. It’s time for uni-
versitiesto contribute their full poten-
tialand for the government to make the
changes necessary to make it happen.
The writer is co-author of ‘The University
Challenge’ with Ed Byrne and a former UK
secretary of state for education
rightly linkingsuccessful institutions
and the welfare of communities rather
than pledging, as some would like, to
reverse university expansion.
A new, sustainable funding structure
must encourage more niversities tou
pursue these missions, and better. Gov-
ernment can take straightforward steps
to achieve that, some of which were rec-
ommended by the Augar review.
The loan system should be extended
to awider range of courses s in coun-a
tries like Australia, New Zealand and
Singapore, including technical educa-
tion and vocational courses other than
law, medicine and the other work-re-
lated degrees taught at university. The
real interest rate for student loans
should be set at zero and the loan repay-
ment income threshold substantially
reduced. Maintenance loans should
fully cover real living costs. Mainte-
nance grants for students from poorer
backgrounds should be reintroduced.
Early loan repayment should be
incentivised and students could be
treated as financially independent
from the age of 18.Research nd teach-a
ing budgets should be separated to
increase transparency — tuition fee
Ministers need to appreciate that the
UK’s strong universities — more so than
governments, corporations or NGOs —
are best placed to offer ways to address
the complex challenges of a fast chang-
ing world including pandemics, terror-
ism, climate change, 5G and the trade
disruptionscaused by Brexit.
World-class research institutions ana-
lyse the problems, identify long and
short-term solutions, and, by educating
about half of all young people, help soci-
ety handle rapid change.
Moreover, there is good evidence
from the US that universities in the UK
are well placed to helpregenerate hoset
localities that have been the biggest los-
ers from globalisation. The Tory mani-
festo promised to “work with local uni-
versities to do more for the education,
health and prosperity of their area” —
in the 2017 election: a few months later
she commissioned theAugar review.
Last May, its recommendations were
published, including reducing the fee
cap to £7,500. But the political toxicity
of the issue meant the latest manifestos
ducked it. Labour kept its vacuous abo-
lition pledge. The Conservatives said
they would look at the interest rates on“
loan repayments with a view to reduc-
ing the burden of debt on students”.
This long period of policy immobility
is now coming to an end.Controversial
reforms are best dealt with early in the
parliament. The new universities minis-
ter hassignalled “crackdown on lowa
quality courses” and Downing Street’s
favourite think-tank has already high-
lighted thepublic trust challengesfac-
ing higher education.
But the system of student finance is so
complex that any reform needs absolute
clarity of purpose. Our original ration-
ale was to raise money for universities
so that resources could be targeted at
schools. The 2012 context was austerity,
so coalition ministers shifted university
costs from the state to individuals. This
government needs to be clear on what it
hopes to achieve with further changes.
I
n 2006 I had lunch with Boris John-
son for the first and only time. As
higher education spokesman for
the opposition, he was looking for
tips in shifting Tory policy away
from outright opposition to university
tuition fees. In that same helpful spirit, I
now offer some suggestions to the prime
minister for urgent reform of the post-
school funding system — which, as he
knows, is working badly. The subject is
moving rapidly up the political agenda.
Since I established the current struc-
ture of university funding in 2004, as
education secretary in a Labour govern-
ment, there has been just one substan-
tial reorganisation. The 2012 reforms
under the Conservative-Liberal Demo-
crat coalition, raising the fee cap from
£3,000 to £9,000, fatally undermined
its sustainability.Theresa May believed
Labour’s pledge to scrap student fees
was a reason for her poor performance
Christine Lagarde, president of the
European Central Bank, felt the need to
issue astatement aying that she, too,s
was “closely monitoring developments”.
There is still a lot we do not know
about Covid-19. But we know what we
need to know for an economic policy
response. The UK government’s medi-
cal advisers, for example, have calcu-
lated that, with existing measures, the
greatest increase in the number of cases
will occur in April, with a peak in May or
June. This implies economic disruption
lasting at least into the summer.
The timeline should be broadly the
same for the eurozone, with the spread
of the virus peaking a little earlier in
Italy, where it started earlier. The direct
impact on the eurozone economy is,
therefore, a hit to supply chains and to
consumption for two or three quarters.
This is a foreseeable and probably sig-
nificanteconomic shock, very different
in effect to Sars and other viruses of the
recent past.
In an ideal world, eurozone govern-
ments would co-ordinate fiscal policy
with each other and also with the ECB.
But there is no sense of urgency. In Ger-
many, for example, a urvey founds hatt
66 per cent of the population think het
situation is under control, while 76 per
cent are not greatly concerned about
becoming infected.
For as long as such delusions persist,
there will be no public pressure for
immediate government action. Ger-
many has announced afiscal stimulusof
a magnitude of 0.008 per cent of gross
domestic product. If there is no political
pressure for a domestic stimulus, then
there will be no support for a co-ordi-
nated response either.
What about monetary policy? During
the eurozone crisis, the ECB was the
only functioning institution of the EU. A
combination of negative interest rates,
quantitative easing and liquidity poli-
cies prevented the eurozone from falling
into a depression. The ECB managed to
ringfence the banking sector and the
money markets. And it managed to
compensate, in part, for the lack of a
mutualised safe asset. But most impor-
tant it was able to neutralise the effects
of austerity, the biggest economic policy
error of our times.
Monetary policy is still the only game
in town. It would be delusional to think
it has no effect. For example, he rise int
the euro’sexchange rate ince the mid-s
dle of February stemmed from the
expectation that the USFederal Reserve
would cut interest rates more aggres-
sively than the ECB. The exchange rate
is one of several channels through which
monetary policy affects the economy.
The big question for the ECB now is
whether it continues to do “whatever it
takes” to support the eurozone econ-
omy when others do not, or whether it
reverts to the mindset of 2011 or earlier.
During that era, policymakers prided
themselves on keeping calm in the face
of adversity.
Ms Lagarde has talked a lot about
green finance and tacklingclimate
change. Important as these issues may
become in the future, I wonder whether
this focus has become too much of a dis-
traction from the more urgent task at
hand. The ECB should not only be dis-
cussing whether it ought to encourage
banks to maintain credit flows to small
and medium-sized companies. It should
also bedealing directly with the eco-
nomic shock from coronavirus that lies
ahead.
The US, China, Japan and the UK are,
at present, more likely to take effective
action than the eurozone. The right pol-
icy will, this time, require a significant
fiscal component. And it will take more
than anItaly-only iscal injection off 0.
per cent of GDP. The whole of the euro-
zone will need a stimulus of at least two
or three times that size. My expectation
is that eurozone policymakers will act
eventually, reluctantly and insuffi-
ciently.
The result of the collective brain fog in
Frankfurt and Brussels would be
entirely negative: another policy-in-
duced recession that will last longer
than it should.
[email protected]
Ideally governments would
co-ordinate fiscal policy
with each other. But there
is no sense of urgency
British universities need a new funding settlement
Charles
Clarke
Employers, who benefit
from a highly-educated
workforce, should
contribute to degree costs
The eurozone is complacent about the coronavirus threat
Opinion
europe
Wolfgang
Münchau
business
Rana
Foroohar
A
merican capitalism feels
divided. Stagnant wages
a n d h i g h c o s t s h av e
squeezed workers, while
companies and investors
have scored record profits and returns.
It has become increasingly clear that the
market benefits some more than others.
So how to repair it? The business lead-
ers who recognise there are faultlines in
the US economy need to start with a few
basic steps. The first is to measure more
precisely in their own companies what
can be improved, and fix it.
Arguably, most important is to gauge
the financial health of their workers.
Chief executives should conduct a
financial stress test of employees to
determine how they are doing and then
establish where changes can be made.
Just Capital Foundation’s polling shows
that Americans holdfair pay and living
wages s two of the top three issues theya
want businesses to prioritise.
PayPal is one company that has taken
note. Under chief executive Dan Schul-
man, PayPal gauged financial stress lev-
els of its hourly and call centre employ-
ees. It found that60 per cent struggled
to make ends meet nd often lived paya
cheque to pay cheque. This compelled
Mr Schulman to raise wages, reduce
healthcare costs, designate employees
as shareholders and promote financial
education — all because PayPal took
time to measure worker wellbeing.
Another step is to report workforce
information. Both private and public
companies should disclose on their web-
sites how many full-time, part-time and
contract workers they have in the US, as
well as the number of staff in each wage
band by increments of $10,000 under
$100,000 (with wider bands above).
Other metrics to include are pay equity
between genders, diversity, paid paren-
tal leave and career development and
tuition reimbursement programmes.
Such disclosure would not only
inform prospective employees. They
would show communities the true eco-
nomic value that a company brings.
There is a big difference between a com-
pany with wages so low that taxpayers
have to subsidise workers, and one that
genuinely provides for its people.
Wages and costs are only part of the
story. Equally valuable is environmen-
tal management and impact. Here, too,
Just Capital has found that the public
cares about a company’s record. Busi-
nesses should detail their carbon foot-
print, and report their biggest liabilities.
This is not just for environmental rea-
sons; a company’s climate behaviour
also brings economic risks and, in some
cases, opportunities.
Sceptics will ask how these disclo-
suresimprove capitalism. The answer is
simple: awareness is the basis for action.
If you don’t measure something, you
will struggle to change it.
If executives can see with granularity
how their workers are doing, they will
know how to help them. If workers see
how their pay stacks up, they will have
more command over their careers. And
if investors get systematic breakdowns
of how companies score by worker, cus-
tomer, environmental and community
(and not just shareholder) metrics, they
can put money into — and benefit from
— just corporate behaviour.
The fallacy of our time is that share-
holders and stakeholders are in a zero-
sum game. But companies that make
Just Capital’s top 100 ranking, b ased on
the priorities of the American public,
have bigger returns on equity, greater
net margins, and enjoy higher valua-
tions than their unranked peers. They
also pay their median workers 31 per
cent more, are 32 per cent more likely to
establish environmental policies, give
8.4 times more to charity and pay living
wages to anestimated 11 per cent more
of their workers.
The picture is clear: successful stake-
holders can also mean successful busi-
ness. Fixing capitalism is a matter of
neither wholesale change nor sticking to
the status quo. It simply requires
rebooting the system to encourage
awareness that can lead to change.
The writer is co-founder and chairman of
Just Capital
A simple
first step for
businesses to
mend capitalism
Paul
Tudor Jones
The fallacy of our time
is that shareholders
and stakeholders are
in a zero-sum game
the fickle fortunes of the market.
All of it was supported by the myth
that share prices are the ultimate indi-
cator of what was happening inside a
company, and ultimately, an economy.
I don’t think that’s really been true for
a long time, something underscored by
last week’sdeath f former Generalo
Electric chief executive Jack Welch. He
came to represent the rise, and ulti-
mately, the fall ofshareholder focused
capitalism. After the 2008 crisis it
became clear that GE’s share price
underWelch had been artificially bol-
stered by debt and leverage.
Welch eventually rejected share-
holder “value” as the “dumbest idea in
the world”. I can only hope that this
market downturn will force more peo-
ple to come to the same conclusion. How
much longer can we run an economy
driven so disproportionately by finan-
cially engineered asset bubbles? The
next few weeks and months may give us
the answer.
[email protected]
receipts. Given the importance of asset
price increases in both tax receipts and
GDP growth, it’s hard to imagine a world
in which the Fed won’t keep cutting
rates indefinitely. Live by the market,
die by the market.
It did not have to be this way, and this
situation did not develop overnight. The
US built an economy that is dangerously
dependent on the whims of Wall Street
little by little, since the 1970s onwards.
It is the result of policy changes driven
by both Democrats and Republicans.
Among them was the 1982 rule that
allowed share buybacks in specific con-
ditions, even though this had once been
considered market manipulation; and
the decision to provide favourable tax
treatment to stock options, which
allowed already fortunate people to
profit from the rising valuations ofcom-
panies they worked for. The most fun-
damental change was the shift from
defined benefit pensions to defined
contribution 401(k) plans, which
has linked the future of so many
Americans, in a Faustian way, to
that the things that make people middle
class — healthcare, education and hous-
ing —have become unaffordable.
Seen in this light, President Donald
Trump’s disingenuous attempts to
equate the fortunes of Wall Street with
those of the country at large make a
kind of grim sense. The value of the S&P
500 is less a gauge of the broad health of
US corporations or consumers than it is
of the wealth of a few tech firms and
value of the 2017 tax cuts. The latter
accounted for wo-thirdst f the aggre-o
gate rise in corporate profits between
2012 and today.
But share price increases represent a
disproportionate amount of the income
tax paid by the top 5 per cent of earners,
who pay 60 per cent of income tax
expectation of wealth held in assets like
stocks and bonds.
What’s stunning is how utterly
dependent American fortunes have
become on the inflation of those asset
prices. Mr Gromen has calculated that
net capital gains plus taxable distribu-
tions from individual retirement
accounts are equal to 200 per cent of
year on year growth in US personal con-
sumption expenditure.
That does not necessarily mean that
people are pulling money out of their
retirement accounts to buy hand-sani-
tiser, bottled water and face masks. But
Mr Gromen argues that it does mean
that US gross domestic product “cannot
mathematically rise if asset prices are
falling”.
No wonder the US Federal Reserve cut
rates by 50 basis points last week. The
move came with a predictable risk of
spooking the market — and it did so. The
S&P 500fell nearly 3 per cent hat day.t
But the fundamental risk of inaction
was deemed greater.
Central bankers are clever people.
They know that they cannot fix pan-
demics or political dysfunction with
monetary stimulus. But in the US more
than anywhere else, they have found
themselves in an unenviable position:
managing an economy that has, over the
last several decades,particularly since
2008, depended on low interest rates to
push up asset prices. That in turn has
made it less obvious to consumers (and
voters) that average real weekly earn-
ings for the bottom 80 per cent are at
about the level they were in 1974 , and
W
atching the markets
these days is like watch-
ing the seven stages of
grief — shock, denial,
anger, bargaining ,
depression, testing and, finally, accept-
ance. We clearly have not reached that
last stage yet. This isn’t really about
coronavirus — that was simply a trigger
for a correction I have long expected.
The US is in the longest economic recov-
ery cycle on record, withmounds of glo-
bal debt, falling credit quality, and dec-
ades of low interest rates driving asset
prices to unsustainable levels.
The reluctance of investors, politi-
cians and central bankers to accept that
is not just an example of the natural
human tendency to put off pain. Rather
it is something scarier and more factual.
The truth is that the US economy is now
dependent on asset bubbles for survival.
This was sharply quantified in a
recent edition of financial analyst Luke
Gromen’s weekly newsletter “The For-
est for the Trees”. About two-thirds of
the US economy isconsumer spending.
But people’s spending patterns are not
based only on their income. Our per-
sonal consumption is also linked to our
A dangerous
dependence
on Wall Street
How much longer can
we run an economy driven
so disproportionately
by asset bubbles?
MARCH 9 2020 Section:Features Time: 3/20208/ - 17:41 User: charlotte.middlehurst Page Name:COMMENT USA, Part,Page,Edition:USA , 17, 1