Financial Times Europe - 12.03.2020

(Greg DeLong) #1
Thursday12 March 2020 ★ FINANCIAL TIMES 9

Opinion


O


ne need not be of the left to
interpretthecenturysofar
as a vindication of the
state. After free enterprise
clinched the cold war, gov-
ernmentallbutapologisedforitselfdur-
ing the 1990s, even with a Democrat
suchasBillClintonasUSpresident.
Since then, we have seen, in order, the
heroism of first-responders on Septem-
ber 11 2001, therecapitalisation of
banks in 2008, and now, as coronavirus
goesaboutitsdirework,thenecessityof
public expertise, public infrastructure,
brutepubliccoercion.Onlyachurloran
ideologue,theirAynRandnovelsfrayed
through overuse, could pretend any one
of these shocks was amenable to a mar-
ketsolution.
It is impossible to know if, or how, the

virus will affect the result of this year’s
US presidential election. Jokers who
liken Donald Trump to the insouciant
mayor inJaws, spurning experts to keep
the economy rolling, forget that he sur-
vived to run Amity Island in the film’s
sequel.Thepresidentisnotyetdonefor,
even if the virus puts his ailing boom
intooutrightreverse.
Perversely, it is easier to guess at the
longer-range consequences of the crisis.
9/11 and the 2008 crash led to not just
the growth of government (today’s
engorged Washington,a city that was
shrinking in 2000, ttests to that) buta
also to a culture change: a new public
tolerance of intrusions. Once-novel air-
port queues and credit barriers quickly
becamethecommonsenseoftheday.
In all likelihood, coronavirus will
bring about a similar tilt in the balance
between the public and private realms.
The terms of political discourse have
moved unmistakably in favour of gov-
ernment over just a few weeks. We are
living through a reputational comeback
for what conservatives have disdained
asthe“administrativestate”.
The legitimacy of government

remains contested in the US as in few
western democracies. Denied “a
monopoly on the legitimate use of vio-
lence” by the second amendment, it
does not even meet Max Weber’s terse
definition of a state. When government
doesexpand,itisoftenasanimprovised
response to trauma. The depression led
to the New Deal, 9/11 to the reversal of
any post-1989 peace dividend, and the

financial crisis to new layers of banking
oversight. War powers that accrued in
the American civil war and the world
wars were repurposed as the legal basis
for welfare. Perhaps only Lyndon John-
son’s war on poverty sprang from one
president’sinnerdrive—forgedinahar-
rowing boyhood — rather than from an
external shock. Even that played out
againstthebloodandfireofurbanriots.

Whether coronavirus will be one of
thesetransformativecrises,wedon’tyet
know. But it is already elevating ques-
tions that can be lamentably secondary
in normal times: about the lack of statu-
tory paid leave, the holes in the health-
care system and, dangerously for Mr
Trump, the deliberate weakening of the
federal bureaucracy’s invisible techno-
crats. His crusade against unelected
know-it-alls made some political sense
when voters felt broadly safe and pros-
perous.BetweennowandNovember,he
pursuesitathisownpoliticalrisk.
In his cheeky new book,10% Less
Democracy, the economist Garett Jones
makes a counter-zeitgeist case for more
“epistocracy”, or rule by the knowledge-
able. Recent weeks have rather made
the case for him, and altered that zeit-
geist. The president now cannot win re-
election without resorting to what his
party otherwise scorns as Big Govern-
ment. As well as the obvious battery of
public health measures, he is toying
with a fiscal stimulus of the kind Repub-
licans viewed as wanton profligacy
underhispredecessorBarackObama.
He is doomed if he does not do these

things. But he is also doomed if he does
them badly. Overnight, competence
matters. Populism has always traded on
the sweet notion that gut instinct, as
opposed to expertise, constitutes a kind
of higher wisdom. This year provides a
far less hospitable atmosphere for such
hokum than 2016. There is electoral
self-harm in the administration’s indif-
ferenceto,well,administration.
The pity of it is that conservatives had
shrewd things to say about government
before the slide into paranoia. Public
choice theory broke through in the
1970s for good reason: bureaucracies,
once founded, do have an interest in
their own aggrandisement. Nor is any
mortal capable of perfect objectivity.
The most scrupulous public servant will
harbour unconscious biases. It is just
that a thing need not be pristine to be
better than the alternative. And the
alternativetotheadministrativestate,if
it could even be defined, does not bear
thinkingabout.Eventsareremindingus
as much. If there are no atheists in fox-
holes,noraretherelibertarians.

[email protected]

Terms of political discourse
have moved unmistakably

in favour of government


over just a few weeks


The administrative state is poised for a comeback


vary depending on where those stake-
holdershappentohavebeenborn?
That would be immoral. It is a virtue,
not a vice, of global companies that they
build relationships of mutual advantage
that do not respect borders. Globalisa-
tionbindsourfortunestogether.
That these bonds makes us collec-
tivelyricherisclear,giventhatthecoun-
tries which have embraced global trade,
along with education and investment,
are the most prosperous. The rise of glo-
balisation since 1990 coincides with
more than a billion people rising out of
extreme poverty. Neither governments
nor companies should turn their back
onthatlegacybecauseofcoronavirus.
Even in the current crisis, globalisa-
tion can make the world safer. That
national economies are fused by the
connective tissue of global companies
means each country has a selfish inter-
est in helping others. That is a source of
stability that anti-globalist rhetoric can
onlyservetodilute.

[email protected]

and floods is demonstrated repeatedly.
Thenextcrisismightstartanywhere.
This is not to deny the value of bring-
ing production closer to demand. In the
garment industry, responding quickly
to changing tastes and advances in tech-
nology make a strong case for “near-
shoring” production. Levi’s isdeploying
fully automated technology or finish-f
ing or “distressing” its jeans with lasers.
This90-secondprocess,completednear
the final market, used to take a worker
inalow-costcountryhalfanhour.
ButcompaniessuchasLevi’sarenear-
shoring to give customers what they
want, not to reduce the risks of interna-
tional trade. Nor are they practising
good global citizenship by “bringing
jobs home”. What is home? Big, modern
companies have customers, employees,
andshareholdersallovertheworld.
That global companies are not crea-
tures of any one country is a point of
attack for globalisation’s critics. But if
we believe that companies have respon-
sibilities to all their stakeholders, do we
really want those responsibilities to

of Harvard Business School points out,
big customers saw the risks and shifted
someoftheirsourcingtoTaiwan.
What they did not do was turn to
domestic chip production. That would
have been a mistake. Microchips are the
perfect example of how local specialis-
ation, spread across the world, creates
better products than is possible in any
one place. The best chip manufacturing
equipment comes from Holland; the
strongest chip designs from the US; the
bestfoundriesareinTaiwan;andsoon.
Nor can companies, with profits at
stake, indulge in Mr Navarro’s fallacy
that all threats originate abroad. The
UK’s domestic coal supplies did not pro-
tect it during the 1980s miners’ strikes.
America’s vulnerability to hurricanes

pull up the economic drawbridge. What
is more surprising is that the Trump
administration is not alone. The virus
has revealed the hidden costs and frag-
ility of global supply chains, triggering a
“backlash”toglobalisation.
Happily, the backlash so far is only
among politicians and pundits. Yes,
some supply chains were shortening
long before the virus hit, and this crisis
will lead to changes in others. But com-
panies still see the advantages of global
trade, consumers still benefit from it,
anditstillmakestheworldasaferplace.
Economically, coronavirus sits along-
side the Fukushima earthquake and
nuclear accident, US-China trade con-
flicts, and other recent global disrup-
tions.Whattheyhaveincommonisthat
they demonstrate the dangers of highly
concentrated, just-in-time supply
chains—notinternationalones.
For too long, companies arranged
their operations with only cost in mind,
says Per Hong, a supply chain consult-
ant atKearney. Yet crises “underline
the need for companies to design their
supply chains around risk competitive-
ness” rather than cost alone. The com-
panies he works with are not localising
supply, but mitigating risk with regional
diversification. “It is the exact opposite
of unwinding the global nature of our
supplychains,”hesays.
Fukushima demonstrated how much
of the global microchipsupply chain
passedthroughJapan,withmanylower-
tier suppliers clustered near the earth-
quake. But afterwards, as Willy Shih

T


here is no longer any doubt-
ing the seriousness ofthe
coronavirus crisis. But we
need to be clear about what
kind of crisis this is. It has
the potential to do worldwide economic
and human harm. But it is not the result
of a flaw in the organisation of the world
economy, in the way people, goods and
money flow across the globe. It is a
globalcrisis,notacrisisofglobalisation.
The distinction is important, because
if politicians and business leaders take
the wrong lessons from this crisis, the
worldwillbelesspreparedforthenext.
It is not surprising that, when
Covid-19 still looked like a Chinese
rather than a global problem, US com-
merce secretary Wilbur Ross said that
the virus, regrettable though it was,
would“help accelerate” thereturn of
jobs to North America. If you see the
worldeconomyasazero-sumgame,one
country’slossmustbeanother’sgain.
For US president Donald Trump’s
trade adviser, Peter Navarro, the virus
shows “we cannot necessarily depend
on other countries, even close allies, to
supply us with needed items”. The best
response to any threat, on his view, is to

Coronavirus


is not a crisis


of globalisation


It is a virtue, not a vice,
of global companies that

they build relationships


that fail to respect borders


AMERICA

Janan


Ganesh


G


etting economic policy
right in turbulent times is
fiendishly hard. Those con-
trollinginterest rates and
taxes irst need to under-f
stand the shock: is coronavirus a hit to
demand, to supply, or both? Then they
must predict human responses: how
and when will consumers and busi-
nessesreact?
Yet there is another difficulty, equally
important, that few sitting in central
banks or finance ministries contem-
plate: the problem of missing data. A
vast unmeasured economy nfluencesi
the markets we measure accurately.
Typicallyseen as a poor-country prob-
lem , this missing economy looks very
likely to grow over the coming decade.
As it does, official economic data and
the policies that result from it are likely
to becomeworse.
The economymissing from our

statisticsis variously tagged as “under-
ground”, “hidden”, “shadow” or “grey”.
None of these labels are very helpful
descriptors: much of what we fail to
capturetakes place at street level, is
vibrant, colourful, self-regulated and
wellorganised.
Some of it is illicit, but most simply
exists outside taxation and government
rules — the street vendors, hawkers,
unregistered pop-up shops and infor-
mal markets that thrive around the
world,forexample.Thiskindofactivity
creates jobs, spending, income and out-
put, which should all be counted in
national gross domestic product but
oftengoesunmeasured.
Recognising their failure, statistical
agencies chip away at the problem.
Some attack data gaps directly,
comparing self-reported tax returns
with the results of audits to gauge the
extent to which sales might be hidden
across an economy. Others use demand
for currency and electricity as an
indirect measure, reasoning that
the need for power and cash should
track the size of informal markets. The
latest attempts use satellite images to
track light emissions as a clue to the

number of unreported factories and
markets.
When figures on the unmeasured
economy emerge, they are perplexing.
It is massive: across 158 countries, the
IMF recently put it at almost 32 per cent
of measured GDP. In emerging and
developingcountriestheshareishigher.
Recent work by local statisticians uts itp
at52percentinIndia,forexample.
In the Democratic Republic of Congo

decent statistics are scant (the last cen-
sus was in 1984) and the unmeasured
economy may be 80 per cent of official
GDP. Because all this unreported activ-
ity bypasses tax and can be unproduc-
tive, it is seen as a drain. The advice
from bodiessuch as the IMF and the
OECD is to tamp it down, fill the fiscal
coffersandboostoutput.
Travelling in places where people live

under acute stress has shown me how
misplaced the mainstream view of
informality can be. Refugee camps tend
to have a handful of registered compa-
nies that international aid agencies deal
with. Among these, thousands of
pop-up shops jostleto provide a choice
of goods and jobs to people under
duress.
Kinshasa is the same story on a much
larger scale: a sprawling mega-village of
10m people, the vast majority working
informally. During recentprotests in
Santiago, an informal market sprang up
to provide essentials including water,
food and nappies. Unmeasured markets
often respond first when timesbecome
tough and are a safety net when govern-
mentsfail.
The rich world has much to do before
dishing out advice. Italy, a G7 member,
misses one-quarter of its economy,
according to IMF estimates. Only Aus-
tria, Switzerland and the US measure
wellenoughthatthemissingeconomyis
below10percentofGDP.
Things could get worse. The over-65s
often pick up informal jobs when
they retire. As this cohort swells,
the unmeasured economy will rise.

Technology, too, is a challenge: the
sharing economy — outfits including
Airbnb — is proving hard to track.
Online networks make informal trade
easier: a social economy of unregistered
takeaways, markets and lending clubs
conductedthroughFacebookisrising.
Unless statisticians catch up, the
result will be bad policy. If measures of
GDP miss the true picture, then the
rules on debt-to-GDP ratios are going to
bewrong,too.
If informal groups are a source of
innovation — an idea that many studies
bear out — then tax breaks and subsi-
dies directed at small and medium-
sized enterprises need rerouting in their
direction.
If the unmeasured economy is large
enough to affect business cycles, as US
Federal Reserve economists have
shown, then interest-raterises and cuts
could be mistimed. Accurate policy
rests on having access to a full picture of
the way people work, earn and spend.
Until we have one, economics can only
bumpalongblindly.

The writer is an economist and the author
of ‘ExtremeEconomies’

A vast, unmeasured
economy exists alongside,

and influences, the markets


we measure accurately


Bumping along blindly is a bad alternative to gathering decent data


Richard
Davies

T


he hope of coronavirus con-
tainmentis giving way to
the strategy of delay. The
disease has reached every
continent bar Antarctica.
Italy, Europe’s worst-affected country,
hasa nationwidequarantine.
Covid-19,forwhichthereisnovaccine
or cure, presents a defining challenge
for any government, whose first duty is
toprotectcitizens.Transparencywillbe
critical if health services become over-
whelmed: the UK is fortunate in having
a public health response led byexperts
who fferedclear,timelyadvice—acon-o
trasttothechaosunfoldingintheUS.
In northern Italy, intensive care beds
are already filling up fast. Healthcare
may be rationed. If so, ethicists say, the
public should be made aware of the rea-
soning behind difficult choices, such as
who will be given intensive care beds
and ventilators in the event of a short-
age. “How will resources be allocated
when demand hits surge and capacity is
limited?” asks Hugh Whittall, director
of the London-based Nuffield Council
on Bioethics, which has led consulta-
tions that have previously fed into an-p
demic planning. “It’s important that the
principles for constructing that guid-
ance are transparent, public and clearly
set out, and that the government pre-
paresthegroundforwhatmightcome.”
The discomfiting idea that some peo-
ple belong at the front of the healthcare
queue is already codified. The US Cent-
ersforDiseaseControl,forexample,pri-
oritises access to limited stocks of pan-

demic flu vaccine by splitting the popu-
lation intofive tiers. Tier 1 occupants
include military personnel deployed
overseas, frontline healthcare workers,
those in the emergency services and law
enforcement, pandemic vaccine manu-
facturers, pharmacists, pregnant
women and children aged 35 months
and under. In a severe pandemic, mor-
tuary staff and energy infrastructure
personnel (tier 2) are favoured over
bankersandtransportworkers(tier3).
Healthy adults aged under 65, if not
included in a higher professional tier,
rank the lowest. Interestingly, priorities
can change according to the profile of a
disease: over-65s are tier 2 in a low
severity pandemic but drop to tier 4 in a
high-severityscenario.
Once illness strikes, that picture
changes. Sick workers are unlikely to
recover in time to assist in the first wave
ofanepidemic. ccupationalusefulnessO
becomes secondary to clinical need, but
healthcareworkersarestillprioritised.
Maxwell Smith, a bioethicist at West-
ern University in Ontario who has writ-
ten widely on pandemic ethics, believes
the 2003 Sars outbreak focused think-
ing onwho should be prioritisedfor life-
saving treatment. Decisions should be
madeinatrustworthy,inclusiveandfair
manner o have legitimacy: “If we’re nott
going to have people upset and protest-
ing, this needs to be done in advance,”
he said. “If we wait until we’re scram-
bling for ventilators, the odds are that
we won’t be able to go through that rea-
soneddecision-makingprocess.”
The broad utilitarian aim of saving
the most lives isdifficult to judge n ai
severe pandemic. The usual “sickest
first”approachcanseeventilatorsbeing
assignedtothosetooilltosurvive.“First
come, first served” might also be jetti-
soned; efficient use of scarce resources
is itself an ethical imperative, meaning
spaces might o to those most likely tog
recover. A “fair innings” argument
favours younger patients but— Cov-
id-19, unlike flu, leaves babies and
youngchildrenrelativelyunscathed.
If the pool of equally needy patients
far exceeds capacity, Mr Smith said, lot-
teriesare an option.Novartisran a lot-
tery o choose the first compassionate-t
use recipients of its $2.1m experimental
gene therapy Zolgensma. Even in
extremis, this is hard on those with los-
ing tickets. It is wiser to improve the
odds now: handwashing and self-isola-
tion can spread the healthcare burden
andbuytimeforavaccine.Ultimately,it
givesmoreofusachanceofwinning.

Thewriterisasciencecommentator

Hard choices


lie ahead


on healthcare


priorities


The discomfiting idea
that some people belong

at the front of the queue


is already codified


SCIENCE


Anjana


Ahuja


BUSINESS


Robert


Armstrong


MARCH 12 2020 Section:Features Time: 3/202011/ - 18:18 User:alistair.hayes Page Name:COMMENT USA, Part,Page,Edition:USA , 9, 1

Free download pdf