The Economist - USA (2020-07-25)

(Antfer) #1

58 Finance & economics The EconomistJuly 25th 2020


1

A


merica’s federal reserve recog-
nised the disruptive potential of elec-
tronic money long ago. “This is a service
which it is expected will be more and more
availed of as the ease and economy of using
it are understood,” its New York arm de-
clared in a report. The year was 1917, and the
Fed had just started allowing banks to
transfer funds by telegram free of any in-
terest charge. More than a century on, cen-
tral banks are grappling with another tech-
nological revolution: the rise of mobile
payments and the turn away from cash.
Just as in the early 20th century, when
central banks created telegraph transfer
networks, they are now coming to the view
that they must design their own digital-
payment networks in order to retain con-
trol of their monetary systems. One idea
gaining favour is to issue a so-called cen-
tral-bank digital currency (cbdc), which
would exist only as electrons on a comput-
er chip, rather than a coin or bill. Roughly
80% of central banks are doing some kind
of cbdcwork, from research to trials, ac-
cording to one survey. Although still early,
it is a trend that could give rise to tantalis-
ing new possibilities for monetary policy.
Most central bankers were sceptical
about cbdcs at first, but in recent months
their views have turned more positive, ac-
cording to an analysis of their speeches by
the Bank for International Settlements
(bis), a club of central banks (see chart).
Partly, that is because they are now more
familiar with the concept. China has al-
ready put the digital yuan into use on a lim-
ited test basis, and Sweden is close to that
with the e-krona. The coronavirus pan-
demic has added to the urgency as more
people shop online or pay with contactless
cards or phones rather than cash.
The primary motivation for issuing a
cbdcis likely to be defensive. The gradual
demise of cash poses two basic risks. First,
online-payment systems could fail, suffer-
ing outages or hacks. To safeguard the in-
tegrity of their currencies, central banks
hope to offer fail-safe digital alternatives.
The second risk is that private-sector
systems are too successful, with more peo-
ple switching to payment platforms of-
fered by big tech firms such as Facebook or
Tencent. Many central banks began taking
this risk more seriously when Facebook
unveiled its plans for a digital currency in


  1. As Hyun Song Shin, head of research
    at the bis, has put it, a shift towards such


currencies would be like moving the econ-
omy from a town-square market—where
all vendors happily accept cash—to compe-
tition between full-service department
stores. Once popular enough, the depart-
ment stores could stop you from shopping
elsewhere and might also introduce new
fees. Regulators could require private pay-
ment platforms to interconnect, but a well-
designed cbdcwould help ensure that this
happens, by forming a digital bridge be-
tween different systems.
European central bankers are most ex-
ercised by the effects of a privately run digi-

tal currency on competition and the con-
sumer interest. The Fed seems farther away
from considering the idea, in part because
Americans are keener on cash.
cbdcs also give central banks more con-
trol. They could allow for transactions to be
easily tracked, perhaps making them more
alluring to China’s authorities. In the West,
where surveys show that the public cares
more about privacy,cbdcs may need to en-
sure anonymity, without circumventing
anti-money-laundering checks.
Where things get really interesting
from a theoretical perspective are the im-
plications for monetary policy. This is par-
ticularly the case if the new currencies are
“retail” cbdcs, made available for use by
the public. (A less exciting option would be
to issue “wholesale” cbdcs exclusively to
commercial banks, much as they already
get funds from the central bank, albeit un-
derpinned by whizzier technology.)
cbdcs may make it easier to implement
negative interest rates. Unlike old-fash-
ioned cash, digital fiat can be programmed.
For now, rates cannot go too negative, be-
cause savers can always demand cash,
which by definition offers an interest rate
of zero. But if digital cash is programmed to
have a negative interest rate, people would
have fewer fallbacks and central banks
more flexibility.
Central bankers might also be tempted
by the potential for targeted interven-
tions—much to the horror of those already
worried about the clout of unelected mon-
etary officials. Rather than lending to com-
mercial banks, central banks would be able
to top up individual currency accounts.
During a downturn, they could transfer
funds to those with low balances. After a
natural disaster, they could direct support

SHANGHAI
A shift from paper to virtual money will give central banks more power

Digital currencies

Bips and bytes


Gaining currency
Number of central bankers’ speeches
on digital currencies, by sentiment

Source:Bankfor
InternationalSettlements

*Availabletothepublic
†Availableonlytobanks

40

20

0

20

40
2016 17 18 2019

↓ Negative

↑ Positive
Wholesale†

Retail*

Netsentiment

Paper’s past it
Free download pdf