A Short History of the Middle Ages Fourth Edition

(Marvins-Underground-K-12) #1

it enhanced aristocratic honor, so dependent on personal generosity, patronage, and


displays of wealth. In the late twelfth century, when some townsmen could boast


fortunes that rivaled the riches of the landed nobility, noble extravagance tended to


exceed income. Most aristocrats went into debt.


The nobles’ need for money coincided with the interests of the peasantry, whose


numbers were expanding. The solution was the extension of farmland. By the middle


of the century, isolated and sporadic attempts to bring new land into cultivation had


become regular and coordinated. Great lords offered special privileges to peasants


who would do the backbreaking work of plowing marginal land. In 1154, for


example, the bishop of Meissen (in Germany) proclaimed a new village and called for


peasants from Flanders to settle there. Experts in drainage, the colonists received


rights to the swampland they reclaimed. They owed only light monetary dues to the


bishop, who nevertheless expected to reap a profit from their tolls and tithes. Similar


encouragement came from lords throughout Europe, especially in northern Italy,


England, Flanders, and Germany. In Flanders, where land was regularly inundated by


seawater, the great monasteries sponsored drainage projects, and canals linking the


cities to the agricultural hinterlands let boats ply the waters to virtually every nook


and cranny of the region.


Sometimes free peasants acted on their own to clear land and relieve the pressure


of overpopulation, as when the small freeholders in England’s Fenland region


cooperated to build banks and dikes to reclaim the land that led out to the North Sea.


Villages were founded on the drained land, and villagers shared responsibility for


repairing and maintaining the dikes even as each peasant family farmed its new


holding individually.


On old estates, the rise in population strained to its breaking point the manse


organization that had developed in Carolingian Europe, where each household was


settled on the land that supported it. Now, in the twelfth century, many peasant


families might live on what had been, in the ninth century, the manse of one family.


Labor services and dues had to be recalculated, and peasants and their lords often


turned services and dues into money rents, payable once a year. With this change,


peasant men gained more control over their plots—they could sell them, will them to


their sons, or even designate a small portion for their daughters. However, for these


privileges they had either to pay extra taxes or, like communes, join together to buy


their collective liberty for a high price, paid out over many years to their lord.


Peasants, like town citizens, gained a new sense of identity and solidarity as they


bargained with a lord keen to increase his income at their expense.

Free download pdf