Environmental Economics 67
optimum amount of pollution. At this optimum, the cost to
society of having less pollution is offset by the benefits to
society of the activity creating the
pollution.
There are two major objections
to the economist’s concept of opti-
mum pollution. First, it is difficult
to determine the true cost of envi-
ronmental damage caused by pollution. The web of rela-
tionships within the environment is extremely intricate and
may be more vulnerable to pollution damage than is ini-
tially obvious, sometimes with disastrous results. When cost
estimates are highly uncertain, economics may lead to poor
decisions. Second, many people find the notion of putting
prices on lives, species, and wilderness to be unethical.
Economic Strategies
for Pollution Control
Command and control regula tions and incentive-based
regulations are two ways that gov-
ernments control pollution. To
date, most pollution control ef-
forts in the United States have
involved command and control
regulation. Sometimes command
and control laws require use of a specific pollution con-
trol method, such as the use of catalytic converters in
cars to decrease polluting exhaust emissions. In other
cases, a quantitative goal is set. For example, the Clean
Air Act Amendments of 1990 established a goal of a 60
percent reduction in nitrogen oxide emissions in pas-
senger cars by the year 2003. Usually, all polluters must
comply with the same rules and regulations, regardless
of their particular circumstances.
Economists are concerned that command and con-
trol regulations can have excessively high costs. They
argue that using economic tools can achieve the same
environmental benefits at lower cost. Consequently,
most economists, whether pro-
gressive or conservative, prefer
incentive-based regulation over
command and control regula-
tion. Ideally, incentive-based
regulation forces producers to
internalize external cost, thereby
achieving the optimum amount
of pollution.
The two most common incentive-based regulatory
approaches are environmental taxes and tradable per-
mits. Environmental taxes are designed to be equal to
the externality caused by a polluter. Unfortunately, this
amount can be highly uncertain and so is often very dif-
ficult to set. Tradable permit approaches, also known as
cap and trade, set an allowable amount of pollution and
then let different companies buy and sell the right to re-
lease that pollution. Companies or individuals who can
easily reduce their emissions sell some of their pollution
rights to those who cannot.
- What is natural capital? How is economics
related to natural capital? - Why are national income accounts incomplete
estimates of total national economic
performance? - How are marginal cost of pollution,
marginal cost of pollution abatement, and
optimum amount of pollution related? - How do command and control regulation and
incentive-based regulation differ regarding
pollution control?
ÃÌqLiiwÌÊ`>}À>ÊUÊ}ÕÀiÊΰ£Ê
Economists identify the optimum amount of pollution as the
amount at which the marginal cost of pollution equals the
marginal cost of pollution abatement (the point at which the two
curves intersect). If more pollution than the optimum is allowed,
the social cost is unacceptably high. If less than the optimum
amount of pollution is allowed, the pollution abatement cost is
unacceptably high.
Amount of pollution (in tons of waste discharge)
Low High
Low
High
Cost per unit of waste (in dollars)
Marginal
cost of
pollution
Marginal cost
of pollution
abatement
Economically
optimum
amount of
pollution
optimum amount
of pollution The
amount of pollution
that is economically
most desirable.
command and
control regulation
Pollution control laws
that work by setting
limits on levels of
pollution.
incentive-based
regulation Pollution
control laws that work
by establishing emis-
sion targets and pro-
viding industries with
incentives to reduce
emissions.