Barron's - USA (2021-02-15)

(Antfer) #1

February 15, 2021 BARRON’S 31


Raising the Floor


American states and cities began raising minimum wages at a


7%yearlyaverageratein2014,liftingtheeffectivenational


minimum wage 75% above the federal minimum.


Source: Ernie Tedeschi


$12


10


8


6


4


2


1995 2000 ’05 ’10 ’15 ’20


Effective national minimum


including state and local laws


Federal statutory minimum


Dollars per hour


THE ECONOMY


After accounting for state and local minimum-


wage laws,the current effective minimum wage


is almost $13 an hour, according to one estimate.


U.S. Minimum Wages


Have Already Jumped,


With Minimal Costs


M


ore than a


quarter of


American


workers—


or roughly


40 million


people—had


jobs that paid less than $15 an hour


before the pandemic. That number


could drop to roughly zero by 2025


if the Raise the Wage Act of 2021


passes in the Senate.


The proposal would more than


double the federal minimum over the


next few years, after which the new


minimum would rise at the same rate


as the national median wage. While


some may fear that the law would


force many businesses to go under or


push millions out of work—a worry


fueled in part by a recent Congressio-


nal Budget Office report—the likelier


outcomes are modestly higher prices


and a notable improvement in living


standards for tens of millions of low-


wage workers and their families.


The first thing to know about


America’s minimum wage is that the


$7.25 an hour federal minimum is sim-


ply too low to do much. Even in Mis-


sissippi, Louisiana, and Alabama—


which have the country’s lowest wage


—more than 90% of workers were


paid more than $8.50 an hour in 2019,


the latest year for which we have com-


prehensive data. And even in the big-


gest low-paid occupations within


those states, such as fast food and


retail, more than 90% of workers


were paid substantially more than


the federal legal minimum.


Recognizing that the federal mini-


mum wage is too low to have a mean-


ingful impact, most states—and many


cities and counties—have imposed


their own minimum wages on top of


the national baseline, as well as sched-


uled increases and automatic inflation


adjustments. After accounting for these


state and local laws, Ernie Tedeschi of


Evercore ISI estimates that the current


effective minimum wage is already


almost $13 an hour—up from less than


$8 an hour as recently as 2014.


Moreover, this effective minimum


will continue to rise even without the


Raise the Wage Act. Even if Congress


does nothing, about 40% of Americans


will end up living in places with a min-


imum wage of at least $15 an hour in a


few years, including everyone in Cali-


fornia, Connecticut, Washington, D.C.,


Florida, Illinois, Massachusetts, Mary-


land, and New Jersey, as well as every-


one in Greater New York City, most of


the Seattle metro area, Denver, Minne-


apolis-St. Paul, and Portland, Ore.


Laura Nicolae, David Mericle, and


Alec Phillips of Goldman Sachs re-


cently estimated that the proposed


schedule to increase the federal mini-


mum wage would therefore have


almost no effect on the country as a


whole until 2024—and even after that,


the impact would be enough only


to sustain the pace of wage growth


expected in 2021-23 under existing


state and local laws.


This means that the proposed fed-


eral wage increases are set to be less


dramatic than what has already oc-


curred since 2014. It also means that


many Americans have already experi-


enced what it’s like to live through a


sharp increase in the minimum wage.


The good news—forinvestors, consum-


ers, and workers alike—is that these


experiences imply that a higher wage


floor would have substantial benefits


for tens of millions of low-paid workers


with few costs for everyone else.


There are two basic explanations


for this benign outcome.


First, economists have found that


higher minimum wages often generate


offsetting benefits for employers in the


form of lower employee turnover and


fewer vacancies, which in turn make it


easier for businesses to boost sales to


meet demand. “An employer may want


100 workers but only has 90 because


they don’t pay enough—and because


they don’t want to raise wages for their


existing workers,” explains Arindrajit


Dube, who advised the Conservative


United Kingdom government on its


minimum-wage policy and who


teaches at the University of Massachu-


setts, Amherst. In these circumstances,


statutory wage increases should be


understood as a fix for uncompetitive


or “oligopsonistic” labor markets.


This is especially true in job markets


where employers have a lot of power to


set wages, whether it’s because employ-


ers use noncompete agreements and


other tactics to suppress worker pay,


because the economy as a whole is


weak, or because there aren’t many


employers to fight over workers—think


of company towns or rural areas. That


last point helps explain why Anna


Godøy and Michael Reich of the Uni-


versity of California, Berkeley, found


that high minimum wages had no neg-


ative impact on employment or hours


worked even in the poorest counties


within states such as California, New


York, Massachusetts, and Washington.


The second reason that large


changes in the minimum wage haven’t


had meaningfully adverse conse-


quences is simply that low-wage labor


costs account for only a small share of


the prices paid by consumers for goods


and services. At Walmart, for example,


“operating, selling, general, and admin-


istrative expenses” are worth only


about a fifth of net sales. Like most


large retailers, the biggest expense, by


far, is the cost of goods sold. For fast-


food franchisees, labor is only one cost


among many, including rent, ingredi-


ents, franchise fees, and depreciation


charges on equipment. Farmworker


wages account for only about a ninth


of the price of produce at the typical


grocery store, according to Phil Martin


of the University of California, Davis.


This means that low-wage employ-


ers can easily pass the cost of higher


wages on to consumers, who probably


won’t even notice the difference. That’s


what happened in Hungary after a dra-


matic increase in the minimum wage


in the early 2000s: middle- and high-


income Hungarians paid somewhat


higher prices to guarantee substantially


higher wages and living standards for


people at the bottom of society, with no


adverse effects on employment in the


services sector. For states such as Mis-


sissippi, Louisiana, and Alabama,


which are about as poor compared


with California and New York as


Hungary is with Germany or France,


the implication is that a big federal


minimum-wage bump would have


minimal costs but substantial benefits.


The macro impact of higher low-


end wages and slightly higher prices


would probably be small, since the


poor, by definition, constitute a tiny


share of national income. But the evi-


dence so far suggests that it would be


positive, with lower consumer debt,


more spending on goods and services,


and higher auto ownership. That


would be good for everyone.B


By Matthew C.


Klein

Free download pdf