AP_Krugman_Textbook

(Niar) #1
the equilibrium in the absence of international capital flows is at point EUSwith an
interest rate of 6%. Panel (b) shows the loanable funds market in Britain, where the
equilibrium in the absence of international capital flows is at point EBwith an inter-
est rate of 2%.
Will the actual interest rate in the United States remain at 6% and that in Britain
at 2%? Not if it is easy for British residents to make loans to Americans. In that case,
British lenders, attracted by high American interest rates, will send some of their
loanable funds to the United States. This capital inflow will increase the quantity of loan-
ablefunds supplied to American borrowers, pushing the U.S. interest rate down. At
the same time, it will reduce the quantity of loanable funds supplied to British bor-
rowers, pushing the British interest rate up. So international capital flows will nar-
row the gap between U.S. and British interest rates.
Let’s further suppose that British lenders regard a loan to an American as being
just as good as a loan to one of their own compatriots, and American borrowers regard
a debt to a British lender as no more costly than a debt to an American lender. In that
case, the flow of funds from Britain to the United States will continue until the gap
between their interest rates is eliminated. In other words, international capital flows
will equalize the interest rates in the two countries. Figure 41.4 shows an international
equilibrium in the loanable funds markets where the equilibrium interest rate is 4% in
both the United States and Britain. At this interest rate, the quantity of loanable
funds demanded by American borrowers exceeds the quantity of loanable funds sup-
plied by American lenders. This gap is filled by “imported” funds—a capital inflow
from Britain. At the same time, the quantity of loanable funds supplied by British
lenders is greater than the quantity of loanable funds demanded by British borrowers.
This excess is “exported” in the form of a capital outflow to the United States. And the
two markets are in equilibrium at a common interest rate of 4%. At that interest rate,
the total quantity of loans demanded by borrowers across the two markets is equal to the
total quantity of loans supplied by lenders across the two markets.
In short, international flows of capital are like international flows of goods and
services. Capital moves from places where it would be cheap in the absence of interna-
tional capital flows to places where it would be expensive in the absence of such flows.

416 section 8 The Open Economy: International Trade and Finance


6%

0

SUS

DUS

Equilibrium
interest
rate in the
United States

Quantity of loanable funds

Interest
rate

EUS

(a) United States (b) Britain

2%

0

SB

DB

Equilibrium
interest rate
in Britain

Quantity of loanable funds

Interest
rate

EB

figure 41.3 Loanable Funds Markets in Two Countries


Here we show two countries, the United States and Britain,
each with its own loanable funds market. The equilibrium in-
terest rate is 6% in the U.S. market but only 2% in the British

market. This creates an incentive for capital to flow from
Britain to the United States.
Free download pdf