investment decisions 7 Portfolio theory and its relevance to real
7.2 The expected value/variance (or mean/variance) criterion
We saw in Chapter 6 that just knowing the expected value of the possible outcomes of a
project is not an adequate basis on which to make decisions. We need some measure
of how the various possible outcomes are arrayed around the expected or mean value.
A popular statistical measure of dispersion is the variance(or its square root, the
standard deviation). The variance (σ^2 ) is defined as follows:
σ^2 = pi[xi−E(x)]^2
where piis the probability of outcome xi, E(x) its expected value or mean, and there are
npossible outcomes.
n
∑
i= 1
A project will yield one of three NPVs whose amount and probabilities of occurrence are as
follows:
NPV Probability
£
−1,000 0.2
−1,000 0.5
+2,000 0.3
What is the expected NPV of the project and its variance?
Example 7.1
The variance is a particularly useful device for our present purposes. It can be
shown (Levy and Sarnat 1988) that if we assume that the range of possible outcomes
from a decision is distributed symmetrically around the expected value (as with both
of the distributions in Figure 6.7 on page 173), then knowledge of the expected value
and the variance (or standard deviation) is all that risk-averse investors need to enable
them to select between two risky investments. In other words, provided that the
investor is risk-averse and that the dispersion of possible outcomes is symmetrical,
then selecting investments on the basis of their expected (or mean) value and variance
will maximise the investor’s utility of wealth. You may recall from Chapter 6 that, as
far as we can judge, nearly all of us are risk-averse, with some of us more risk-averse
than others.
ENPV =(0.2 ×−1,000) +(0.5 ×1,000) +(0.3 ×2,000)
=£900
s^2 =0.2(−1,000 −900)^2 +0.5(1,000 −900)^2 +0.3(2,000 −900)^2
=(0.2 ×3,610,000) +(0.5 ×10,000) +(0.3 ×1,210,000)
s^2 =1,090,000 (in £^2 )
Solution
‘
‘