The Econmist - USA (2021-10-30)

(Antfer) #1

30 Special report Stabilising the climate TheEconomistOctober30th 2021


 A list of acknowledgments and sources is included in the online version
of this special report
   Reprints of this special report are available, with a minimum order
of five copies. For academic institutions the minimum order is  and for companies .
We also offer a customisation service. To order, contact Foster Printing Service:
Tel: +   ; email: [email protected]
For information on reusing the articles featured in this special report, or for copyright queries,
contact The Economist Rights and Syndication Department: Tel: + ()  ;
email: [email protected]
   Previous special reports can be found at
Economist.com/specialreports

pre­industriallevels—iftheystabiliseatall.
Thealternativetothisgameofchickenwouldbetomeetthe
Paristemperaturelimitsthroughothermeans.Solargeoengineer­
ingisanapproachtotheclimatethatconcentratesnotonmaking
iteasierfortheEarthtocoolitself,asremovingcarbondioxide
does,butstoppingit fromwarmingsomuchinthefirstplace.The
wayofdoingthiswhichhasbeenstudiedinmostdetail,albeital­
mostentirelyinmodels,istocreatea thinlayerofreflectivepart­
iclesinthestratospherethatreflectssunlightbackintospacebe­
foreit warmsthesurface.Studiessuggestthat,forgoodorill,such
a schemecouldbeimplementedbya relativelysmallfleetofpur­
pose­builtaircraft.
Theseideashave,forunderstandablereasons,longbeenmar­
ginalisedinpolicycircles.Theyreekofhubrisandthepotential
forunintendedconsequences.Andif,byprovidinganotherwayof
limitingtemperaturerises,theyreducetheperceivedurgencyof
curbingemissions,theymightweakenorevenstallthecommit­
menttoemissionsreduction.
Thatwouldbedisastrous.Thoughithastheoppositeeffecton
temperature,thecoolingofferedbysolargeoengineeringisnot,in
physicalterms,anexactcounterofthewarmingcreatedbygreen­
housegases.Onedifferenceisseenintheworld’shydrologicalcy­
cle;solargeoengineeringtendsto suppressprecipitation.The
moretheworldcametorelyonit,themorethisandothermis­
matcheswouldbecomeharmful.This,alongsidethefactthatit
doesnothingaboutoceanacidification,isa strongpartoftherea­
sonwhyresearcherslookingseriouslyatsolargeoengineering
neveradvocateusingit insteadofmitigation.Thosenotturnedoff
byit completelyseeit asa possiblecomplementtomitigation,not
asanalternative.
Inthisitisverylikenegativeemissions—onereasontheyare
sometimescalled“carbongeoengineering”.Thewaya solar­geo­
engineeringcapabilitymightreducetheincentivetocontinue
withemissionsreductionissimilartothewayexistingnegative­
emissionscapacitymightwork.Andinbothcasesthatreduced
ambitionmightwellcomeabouteveniftheproposedgeoengi­
neeringdidnot.
A crucialdifferencebetweenthetwo,though,isthecostofin­
stigatingthem.Itseemslikelythatputtinga veilintotheatmo­
spherewouldbecomparativelycheap(inthetensofbillionsof
dollarsa year,perhapsevenless),thoughtheexternalitiesnotin­
cludedinthecostmightbehigh.Anotherdifferenceisthatnega­
tiveemissionswouldaffecttheclimateinmoreorlessthesame
waywhoeverundertookthem;theworld’scarbon­dioxidelevelis
whatitis.Differentsortsofsolargeoengineering,though,would
havedistinctlydifferentregionaleffects.

Designforliving
If the world as a whole were able to design a solar­geoengineering
scheme, studies suggest it could come up with one that provided
climate  benefits  to  almost  everyone  and  serious  problems  to  al­
most  nobody.  A  plausible  way  to  use  such  an  optimal  scheme
might be to offset the temperature rise caused by overshooting the
carbon budget. That would provide a sort of breathing space to al­
low  the  excess  CO 2 to  be  drawn  down  more  slowly  and  cheaply
than would be necessary if its warming effects were actually being
felt. A comparatively gentle acceleration of chemical weathering,
rather  than  a  huge  investment  in  dacor  other  schemes,  might
prove  sufficient.  As  those  measures  slowly  wore  the  overshoot
down  the  solar  geoengineering  could  be  reduced.  When  the  CO 2
level was low enough it would  be phased out completely, leaving
behind a stable climate.
But  the  world  as  a  whole  might  not  get  to  choose  the  wisest
path. A small group of countries, or even a single large one, could
undertake  a  solar­geoengineering  scheme  unilaterally.  Such  a

club  would  be  likely  to  optimise  its  own  interests  rather  than
those  of  the  world.  It  might,  for  example,  choose  to  cool  some
places to a degree that, because of geoengineering’s effects on the
water cycle, risked desiccating others. That might lead to resent­
ment, rancour or reprisals.
Nor  would  any  given  set  of  solar  geoengineers  be  sure  to  get
things  their  own  way.  The  late  Marty  Weitzman,  a  pioneering
economist  of  climate  change,  pointed  out  that  though  emission
reductions  (and  by  implication  negative  emissions),  because  of
their  cost,  have  a  free­rider  problem,  solar  geoengineering,  be­
cause it looks cheap, has a “free­driver” problem. Where free­rider
problems lead to underprovision (countries are unwilling to com­
mit to cutting emissions when others do not, as 26 years of cops
has made clear) free­driver problems may lead to overprovision.
Solar geoengineering looks cheap enough that countries wanting
more of it can provide it unilaterally, whatever others think.
This  implies  that,  other  things  being  equal,  the  level  of  solar
geoengineering would be a trade­off between the amount that the
most enthusiastic countries wanted and the amount that the least
enthusiastic  would  endure  before  taking  decisive  action,  quite
possibly through force of arms. Another game of chicken. 
The  difficulties  involved  in  negative
emissions  and  solar  geoengineering  are
very different, and the second looks much
more unfamiliar and threatening than the
first. But in both cases the problem is fun­
damentally similar—and closely related to
the contradiction between global tempera­
ture  goals  and  national  emissions­reduc­
tion commitments at the heart of the Paris
agreement. The world has needs which can
be  agreed  on;  but  the  decisions  necessary
to meet those needs are made by countries
which differ in their interests, their capabilities and the amount of
persuasion  they  can  exert  or  resist.  The  responsibilities  may  be
common; the differentiation is endless.
Glasgow will show the degree to which national governments
are able to deliver progress in terms of the increased ambition of
their  ndcs,  the  realisation  of  long­promised  transfers  of  money
from north to south, and workable rules for the parts of the Paris
agreement  which  remain  sketchy.  The  progress  is  unlikely  to  be
spectacular, reinforcing the point that managing global issues like
the  climate  purely  through  national  lenses  is  impractical.  But
coming up with an alternative in which individual countries will
allow  the  interests  of  others  to  be  placed  above  their  own  is  im­
plausible. And if the world is to stabilise the climate at an accept­
able level, something will have to give. 
The climate crisis was brought about as part of the creation of a
new world economy. Coming throughitsuccessfully may well re­
quire a new world politics. Failingtodoso will be calamitous in
terms of politics and economics alike.n

It seems likely
that putting a veil
into the atmo-
sphere would be
comparatively
cheap
Free download pdf