108156.pdf

(backadmin) #1

  1. Option Pricing 187


a probabilityP∗such thatV(t)=W(t)+


(

m−r+^12 σ^2

)

t/σ (rather than
W(t) itself) becomes a Wiener process underP∗, then the exponential factor
e(m−r+^12 σ


(^2) )t
will be eliminated from the final expression. (The existence of such
a probabilityP∗follows from an advanced result in Stochastic Calculus, the so-
calledGirsanov theorem.) Indeed, sinceV(t) has density√^12 πte−x
2
2 t underP∗,
that is, it is normally distributed with mean 0 and variancet, it follows that
E∗


(

e−rtS(t)

)

=S(0)E∗

(

eσW(t)+(m−r)t

)

=S(0)E∗

(

eσV(t)−

(^12) σ (^2) t)


=S(0)

∫∞

−∞

eσx−

(^12) σ (^2) t√ 1
2 πt
e−
x 22 t
dx


=S(0)

∫∞

−∞

√^1

2 πt

e−

(x− 2 σtt)^2
dx

=S(0)

∫∞

−∞

√^1

2 πt

e−

y 22 t
dy=S(0).

The fact thatE∗(e−rtS(t)) =S(0) does not depend on timetis a necessary
condition for the discounted price process e−rtS(t) to be a martingale underP∗.
To show that e−rtS(t) is indeed a martingale underP∗we need in fact to verify
the stronger condition


E∗

(

e−rtS(t)|S(u)

)

=e−ruS(u) (8.7)

for anyt≥u≥0, involving the conditional expectation of e−rtS(t)givenS(u).
So far we have dealt with conditional expectation where the condition was
given in terms of a discrete random variable, see Section 3.2.2. Here, however,
the condition is expressed in terms ofS(u), a random variable with continuous
distribution. In this case the precise mathematical meaning of (8.7) is that for
everya> 0
E∗


(

e−rtS(t)1S(u)<a

)

=E∗

(

e−ruS(u)1S(u)<a

)

, (8.8)

where 1S(u)<ais theindicator random variable,equalto1ifS(u)<aand to 0
ifS(u)≥a.


Exercise 8.13


Verify equality (8.8).

Exercise 8.14


Find the density ofW(t) under the risk-neutral probabilityP∗.
Free download pdf