108156.pdf

(backadmin) #1

  1. Introduction: A Simple Market Model 9


This way, you will be holding a portfolio (x, y) withx= 1 shares of stock
andy=−1 bonds.The time 0 value of this portfolio is


V(0) = 0.

At time 1 the value will become


V(1) =

{

Su−A(1) if stock goes up,
Sd−A(1) if stock goes down.

IfA(1)≤Sd, then the first of these two possible values is strictly positive,
while the other one is non-negative, that is,V(1) is a non-negative random
variable such thatV(1)>0 with probabilityp>0. The portfolio provides an
arbitrage opportunity, violating the No-Arbitrage Principle.
Now suppose thatA(1)≥Su. If this is the case, then at time 0:



  • Sell short one share for $100.

  • Invest $100 risk-free.


As a result, you will be holding a portfolio (x, y) withx=−1andy= 1, again
of zero initial value,
V(0) = 0.


The final value of this portfolio will be


V(1) =

{

−Su+A(1) if stock goes up,
−Sd+A(1) if stock goes down,

which is non-negative, with the second value being strictly positive, since
A(1)≥Su.Thus,V(1) is a non-negative random variable such thatV(1)> 0
with probability 1−p> 0 .Once again, this indicates an arbitrage opportunity,
violating the No-Arbitrage Principle.


The common sense reasoning behind the above argument is straightforward:
Buy cheap assets and sell (or sell short) expensive ones, pocketing the difference.


1.4 Risk and Return


LetA(0) = 100 andA(1) = 110 dollars, as before, butS(0) = 80 dollars and


S(1) =

{

100 with probability 0.8,
60 with probability 0.2.
Free download pdf