24 Briefing Government spending TheEconomistNovember20th 2021
hear that, from 1948 to 1984, the British
state ran its own chain of hotels, that is be
cause the “neoliberal” outlook on the prop
er place of government has triumphed.
Yet in other areas today’s governments
have more power than ever. Building
things requires developers to jump
through more environmental, conserva
tion and localopposition hoops than it
used to. Healthandsafety laws have pro
liferated. Occupational licensing has
grown dramatically across Europe and
North America.
For decades unions in many rich coun
tries successfully argued against govern
mentimposed minimum wages, saying
they would do a better job of raising pay
themselves. But as they have withered, the
government has stepped in to provide
wage floors. Rules relating to other work
place matters such as parental leave and
genderpay gaps go in only one direction.
And if direct government control of the
economy has weakened, it has been more
than replaced by redistribution. The objec
tive correlative of Mr Clinton’s claim that
the era of big government was over took
the form of tax credits; he tripled those for
low earners with children, and introduced
the universal credit for children that Mr Bi
den now wishes to expand. In 1979 the bot
tom fifth of American earners received
meanstested transfers worth on average
32% of their pretax income, according to
the Congressional Budget Office. By 2018
the figure was 68%.Total socialprotection
spending in the oecd—comprising cash
benefits, direct inkind provision of goods
and services, and “tax breaks with social
purposes”—grew from 15% of gdpin 1980
to 20% in 2019.
Three forces stand out as driving the
trend: the incentives which bureaucrats
and politicians face; the rising costs of ser
vices provided by the government; and the
demands of voters.
Governments and bureaucrats are at
least partly selfinterested: “publicchoice
theory” says that unrestrained bureaucra
cies will defend their turf and seek to ex
pand it. A good recent example would be
central banks. Their mandates typically
compel them to control inflation and see
off bank runs. Yet in recent years, with a
cursory and often unconvincing nod to
those mandates, central bankers have tak
en on fresh responsibilities. America’s
Federal Reserve seems to believe it has
both the obligation and the tools to reduce
racial inequality, while many central bank
ers want to raise the relative cost of capital
for fossilfuel companiesvia interventions
in the corporatebond market.
Politicians have their own incentives to
expand the state. It is generally more re
warding for a politician to introduce a new
programme than it is to close an old one
down; costs are spread across all taxpayers
while benefits tend to be concentrated,
thus eliciting gratitude from interest
groupsandsometimesevenvoters.
Technology,inparticularcommunica
tionstechnology,hasservedtostrengthen
the bureaucracy’sgrasp.Itis nocoinci
dencethatbiggergovernmentsemergedat
roughlythesamepointinthe20thcentury
aslargecorporations,whichalsorequired
a new communications infrastructure.
Morerapideconomicgrowthpoweredby
thosenewarrangementsmadethegrowth
ofgovernment lessburdensome than it
mighthavebeen.
Hardlycromulent
Thesecondbroadfactorbehindthegrow
ingpowerofthestateiswhatWilliamBau
mol,aneconomist,named“costdisease”.
Inthe1960sBaumolnotedthatproductivi
tyinsomesectorsisgreaterthaninothers.
Butwagesmustriseinlessproductivesec
torsastheyriseinmoreproductivesectors
topreventworkersquitting.Sodespitethe
factthatanorchestraattheRoyalAlbert
Hallcontainsaboutthesamenumberof
musiciansasit didwhenthevenueopened
in1871,eachmusicianispaida lotmoreto
day,giventhevastlygreateropportunities
thatareonofferintheeconomy.
Alotofgovernmentspendingisinar
easwherelabourproductivity growthis
slow,mostnotablytheprovisionofeduca
tionandhealthcare(seechart3 onnext
page).Astherealwagesofdoctors,nurses
andteachersgoupataratesetbyother
partsoftheeconomy,sodoesspending.
Whatismore,educationandhealthcare
arealsowhateconomistscall“superior”
goods.Aspeoplebecomerichertheyspend
a higherfractionoftheirincomeonthem.
Ifitisthegovernmentthatprovidesthose
services,itmustspendmore.Acrossthe
oecd overall health spending has risen
from8%ofgdpin 2005 to10%,andgovern
mentsareresponsibleforthebulkofthat.
OthershaveextendedBaumol’sideas,
arguingthatgovernmentinterventionin
hibitsproductivitygrowth.A recentreport
by Steven Teles, Samuel Hammond and
DanielTakashoftheNiskanenCentre,a
thinktankinWashington,dc, warnsofa
viciouscycleinwhichsubsidiesforservic
esthesupplyofwhichisconstrainedby
regulations,suchashousingandeduca
tion,pushupprices,creatingdemandsfor
furthersubsidies.Oneexampleisstudent
loans:inAmerica60%ofanyincreasein
themaximumsubsidisedloanispassed
throughintohighertuitionfees,according
toa studybytheFederalReserveBankof
New York. American politics is replete
with promises of further subsidies for
highereducation.Pledgestoreducecosts
arethinontheground.
Thefinalsteroidisthevoters’appetite,
whichdependsonwhothevotersare.Over
thecourseofthe20thcenturyincreasing
numberswereworkingclassandincreas
ingnumberswerewomen.Politicalscien
tistshavelinkedtheexpansionofwomen’s
suffrageacrosstherichworldtogrowthin
socialspending,especiallyonhealthand
education.
Twentiethcentury voters were also
increasingly likelyto have fought in or
Spotthetrend
Governmentspending ,%ofGDP
Sources:VitoTanziandLudgerSchuknecht;IMF;OECD;AMECO *Forecast †1870-1937centralgovernment,1960- 0 1general government
2
60
40
20
0
1870 2021*
Austria
1870 2021*
Britain
1870 2021*
France
1870 2021*
Germany
60
40
20
0
1870 2021*
Italy
60
40
20
0
1870 2021*
Japan
1870 2021*
Spain†
1870 2021*
Sweden
1870 2021*
Switzerland
60
40
20
0
1870 2021*
United States
An era unended
United States, federal spending by source
% of GDP
1
Sources:Congressional Budget Oce;
Oceof Management and Budget
Netinterest
Net mandatory
Discretionary
30
20
10
0
40
201020009080701962