Encyclopedia of Sociology

(Marcin) #1
CONFLICT THEORY

WHAT CONSTITUTES A CONFLICT
GROUP?

For Marx and Engels, a society’s conflicting inter-
ests derive from the division between owners and
nonowners of property. Dahrendorf (1959) pro-
posed that conflicts are based on power, dividing
order-givers, who have an interest in maintaining
the status quo, from order-takers, who have an
interest in changing it. Property is only one of the
bases of power conflict, and conflicts can be ex-
pected inside any type of organization, including
socialist ones. In the Weberian model there are
even more types of conflict, since every cultural
group (such as ethnic, religious, or intellectual
groups) can also struggle for advantage. In addi-
tion, economic conflict takes place in three differ-
ent types of market relations, pitting employers
against workers, producers against consumers, and
lenders against borrowers (Wiley 1967). Gender
stratification produces yet another dimension of
conflict.


THE PROCESS OF CONFLICT

Conflicting interests remain latent until a group
becomes mobilized for active struggle. This occurs
when its members are physically concentrated,
have material resources for communicating among
themselves, and share a similar culture. The high-
er social classes are typically more mobilized than
lower classes, and most struggles over power take
place among different factions of the higher class-
es. Lower classes tend to be fragmented into local-
ized groups and are most easily mobilized when
they are a homogeneous ethnic or religious group
concentrated in a particular place. The better
organized a conflict group is, the longer and more
intensely it can struggle; such struggles become
routinized, as in the case of entrenched labor
unions or political parties. Less organized conflict
groups that become temporarily mobilized are
more likely to be violent but unable to sustain the
conflict.


Overt conflict increases the solidarity of groups
on both sides. Coser (1956), elaborating the theo-
ry of Georg Simmel, points out that conflict leads
to a centralization of power within each group and
motivates groups to seek allies. A conflict thus
tends to polarize a society into two factions, or a
world of warring states into two alliances. This


process is limited when there are cross-cutting
memberships among groups, for instance, if class,
ethnic, and religious categories overlap. In these
cases, mobilization of one line of conflict (e.g.,
class conflict) puts a strain on other dimensions of
conflict (e.g., ethnic identity). Thus, cross-cutting
conflicts tend to neutralize each other. Converse-
ly, when multiple lines of group membership are
superimposed, conflicts are more extreme.
Conflicts escalate as each group retaliates
against offenses received from the other. How
long this process of escalation continues depends
on how much resources a group can draw upon: its
numbers of supporters, its weapons, and its eco-
nomic goods. If one group has many more re-
sources than the other, the conflict ends when the
mobilizing capacity of the weaker side is exhaust-
ed. When both sides have further resources they
have not yet mobilized, escalation continues. This
is especially likely when one or both sides have
sustained enough damage to outrage and mobilize
their supporters but not great enough damage to
destroy their organizational resources for struggle.
Deescalation of conflict occurs in two very
different ways. If one side has overwhelming supe-
riority over the other, it can destroy opposition by
breaking the other group’s organizational capacity
to fight. The result is not harmony but an uneasy
peace, in which the defeated party has been turned
back into an unmobilized latent interest. If neither
side is able to break up the other’s organization,
conflict eventually deescalates when resources are
eaten up and the prospects of winning become
dimmer. Although wars usually arouse popular
solidarity at first, costs and casualties reduce en-
thusiasm and bring most wars to an end within a
few years. Civilian uprisings, strikes, and other
small-scale conflicts typically have fewer resources
to sustain them; these conflicts deescalate more
quickly. During a deescalation, the points of con-
tention among the opponents modulate from ex-
treme demands toward compromises and piece-
meal negotiation of smaller issues (Kriesberg 1982).
Very destructive levels of conflict tend to end
more rapidly than moderate conflicts in which
resources are continuously replenished.

COERCIVE POWER AND REVOLUTION

In a highly coercive state, such as a traditional
aristocracy or a military dictatorship, power is
Free download pdf