00Thaler_FM i-xxvi.qxd

(Nora) #1
In the case of the parameters used for the table in section 4.2.,
q



  • =0.28 and q–=0.95.
    There is no loss of generality in restricting the support of qtto the
    interval [q


     ,q–]. Certainly, an investor can have prior beliefs that lie

    outside this interval, but with probability one, qtwill eventually be-
    long to this interval, and will then stay within the interval forever.
    We are now ready to begin the main argument of the proof. Un-
    derreaction means that the expected return following a positive
    shock should exceed the expected return following a negative shock.
    In other words,




Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=+y)−Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=−y)>0.
Overreaction means that the expected return following a series of
positive shocks is smaller than the expected return following a series
of negative shocks. In other words, there exists some number J≥1,
such that for all j≥J,

Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=yt− 1 =...=yt−j=y)
−Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=yt− 1 =...=yt−j=−y)<0.

Proposition 2 provides sufficient conditions on p 1 and p 2 so that
these two inequalities hold. A useful function for the purposes of
our analysis is
f(q)=Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=+y, qt=q)−Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=−y, qt=q).
The function f(q) is the difference between the expected return
following a positive shock and that following a negative shock,
where we also condition on qtequaling a specific value q. It is sim-
ple enough to write down an explicit expression for this function.
Since

we find

E( , ) ()

()() ()

()(()())

ttPPy yqqtt t

y
yp q

y
yp pq yp q yp q

ypq p yp q q

+ −=+== +







+−− − − +







=−+ +

12

12 2 2

21

1
2 2

1
2
1
2

22


δ

δ


∆∆

∆∆

PP
y
yyppqypqq

yypqq

tt

t
tt tttt

tttt

+

+
++

++

−= + − − − −

−− −

1

1
112 21

121

δ

()( )()

()(),

454 BARBERIS, SHLEIFER, VISHNY

Free download pdf