accumulate cash. So there is no reason that the issuance of “cheap stock”
should lower the hurdle rate for investment.
2.binding capital structure constraint,
no price-pressure effects
The next case to examine is one in which the capital structure constraint is
binding, but where price-pressure effects are absent—that is, one in which
dZ/dL≠0 and di/dE=0. In this case, Eq. (14) simplifies to
df/dK=D(1+k*)+(1−D)(1+CER). (15)
Based on Eq. (15), we have:
Proposition 4.When the capital structure constraint is binding and
there are no price-pressure considerations, the optimal hurdle rate
has the following properties: the hurdle rate is between the NEER
and FAR values of CER and k*, respectively; as Dapproaches 0, the
hurdle rate converges to CER, as in Proposition 1; as Dapproaches
1, the hurdle rate converges to k*, as in Proposition 2.
The intuition behind Proposition 4 is very simple. When capital structure
imposes a binding constraint, one cannot, in general, separate investment
and financing decisions. This is perhaps easiest to see in the case where
δ<0, so that the stock is undervalued and the firm would like to repur-
chase shares. For each dollar that is devoted to investment, there is less cash
available to engage in such repurchases, holding the capital structure fixed.
RATIONAL CAPITAL BUDGETING 617