The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_C Date:31/3/09
Time:21:45:54 Filepath://ppdys1108/BlackwellCup/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-
9781405132879/appln/3B2/revises/9781405132879_4_C.3d


powers in question do not pertain to the own-
ership or control of things in general, but spe-
cifically to resources or assetsas they are deployed
in production. The fundamental contrast in cap-
italist societies, for example, is between owners
of means of production (machines, inputs,
space etc.) and owners of labour power, where
each category of owner – the capitalist and the
labourer – deploys the resource that they own
in production. That said, it is worth emphasi-
zing that class relations as defined are elastic
enough to recognize patriarchy within
the household and beyond and racial discrimin-
ation within society (seeracism) as concurrent
class processes. Meanwhile, work inradical
geography has convincingly shown that
exploitative class relations are fundamentally
spatial and that this spatial organization is crit-
ical to understanding the nature ofuneven
development.
The ambiguity of class location – or location
within social relations of production – is force-
fully illustrated by managers within corpor-
ations, who exhibit the rights and powers of
both capital (they can hire and fire workers,
make decisions about new technologies and
changes in the labour process, etc.)andlabour
(they cannot sell a factory, they have limited
discretion in the use of surplus or profit, they
can be fired from their jobs if the owners are
unhappy, etc.). Workers as corporate share-
holders (via an employee stock ownership
plan, for example) provide another vivid illus-
tration of ambiguity, since they simultaneously
occupy two class locations. Other instances
that complicate the empirical exercise of class
location include persons who work at two jobs,
one as a worker in a firm and the other
as a self-employed tradesman; professional
women, who employ a full-time housemaid;
or historically, working-class sepoys stationed
in colonies who, by virtue of racial difference,
found themselves in positions of class super-
iorityvis-a`-visnatives (one imagines a similar
phenomenon at work in today’s imperial out-
posts). In short, class relations, class structure
and class location in societies are complex – as
such, we should presuppose neither unity of
purpose (class interest) nor consciousness
(class agency) within a given class category
(see Marx, 1963 [1852]).
The German sociologist Max Weber’s
analysis of class is the primary alternative to
Marxist class analysis. In Weber’s scheme,
classes are distinguished by positions of rela-
tive advantage and disadvantage in terms of
wealth and income. He writes: ‘We may speak
of a ‘‘class’’ when (1) a number of people have

in common a specific causal component of
their life chances, in so far as (2) this compon-
ent is represented exclusively by economic
interests in the possession of goods and oppor-
tunities for income, and (3) is represented
under the conditions of the commodity or
labor markets’ (Weber 1968 [1946], p. 181).
While there are overlaps here with Marx’s
understanding of class, there are also clear
differences. Weber, for instance, emphasizes
‘personal life experiences’ and ‘life chances’
as critical aspects of ‘class situation’, and takes
class to be ‘any group of people that is found
in the same class situation’ (ibid.). Thus,
whereas for Marx class is an objective set of
social relations, for Weber subjective elements
become key. Also in contrast to the Marxist
view ofclass as relational, the Weberian view
emphasizesclass as market position. Classes are
hierarchical arrangements, but potentially
dynamic ones becausemarketposition may
be changed by collective strategies in the
labour market (e.g. through professional asso-
ciations or trades unions). In underscoring the
‘life chances’ that accompany ‘class situation’,
Weber draws attention to individuals’ pro-
spective ‘personal life experiences’: ‘the prob-
abilities of social and occupational mobility; of
educational access and achievement; of illness
and mortality’ (Clarke 2005, p. 40). While
classes, in Weber’s view, derive unambigu-
ously from economic interest, they are linked
to political organization (party) and social pos-
ition (status), both of which may be shaped by
non-economic processes and may influence
‘class-consciousness’. The French sociologist
Pierre Bourdieu is a prominent example of a
scholar who has creatively fused the Marxist
and Weberian perspectives of class in his
analysis of various forms ofcapital. vg

Suggested reading
Bourdieu (1984); Massey (1995); Weber (1968
[1946]); Wright (2005).

class interval A key element in the design of
a quantitativemapthat partitions the range
of data values into discrete categories, each
assigned a unique symbol. Common onchor-
oplethmaps, class intervals are also used
for maps of linear and point phenomena
and embedded in maps on whichisolines
divide the data into categories or layers.
Typically, a map key links the class intervals
to their respective symbols, which may vary
in size, greytone value or colour. Because
different class intervals can yield radically
different depictions of the same data, viewers

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_C Final Proof page 89 31.3.2009 9:45pm

CLASS INTERVAL
Free download pdf