The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_C Date:31/3/09
Time:21:45:55 Filepath://ppdys1108/BlackwellCup/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-
9781405132879/appln/3B2/revises/9781405132879_4_C.3d


of inequality as a consequence of entangled
nationalandtransnationalprocesses(fromstate
welfare decisions to globalneo-liberalismand
the acts oftransnational corporationsand
financialinstitutions);aphenomenonrequiring
transnational interventions, but all too fre-
quently treated by national elites as a domestic
issue (see also transnationalism). Finally,
Beck refers to ‘banal cosmopolitanism’ based
around the everyday consumption of products
and images from around the world, and the
increasing formation of cultural practices and
affiliations through world engagement.
The sum of these few examples of a multi-
dimensional process is the claim that ‘the
experiential space of separate national soci-
eties, each with its own uniform language,
identity and politics, is becoming more and
more of a myth’, as what counts as national
becomes ‘in its essence increasingly trans-
national or cosmopolitan’ (Beck, 2004,
p. 153). This does not in any way mean that
we are all becoming cosmopolitans, but it does
question how far accounts of what goes on
withinnationscan afford to ignore the world
at large. These considerations have prompted
some geographers to revisit the history of
geography (seegeography, history of), not
to condemn its contributionstout courtbut
to offer nuanced readings of its engagement
with cosmopolitan ideals (Cosgrove, 2003;
cf. Harvey 2000a), while others have sought
to energize the contemporary project of acrit-
ical human geographyby reflecting on the
implications of cosmopolitanism forethics
(e.g. Popke, 2007) and for political action
(e.g. Gidwani, 2006). aa

cost structure The division of the total cost
of production into its constituent parts, or the
cost of individual inputs. For example, the
cost structure of the iron and steel industry
would indicate absolute (or relative) amounts
of expenditure on iron ore, coking coal, lime-
stone, labour, capital equipment and so on.
The cost structure thus reveals whether a par-
ticular activity is material intensive,capital
intensive, labour intensive and so on, with
respect to expenditure on inputs. This infor-
mation can provide an initial clue to the inputs
likely to have the greatest bearing on the loca-
tion of the activity in question. dms

cost^benefit analysis An analytical proced-
ure for the comprehensive, frequentlyex ante,
economic evaluation of major public-sector
projects, embracing their full positive and
negative societal consequences, sometimes

over the range of project options and geo-
graphical scales (e.g. Turner, Adger and
Doktor, 1995). As such, cost–benefit analysis
(commonly ‘CBA’) covers a wider range of con-
siderations than the profit-and-loss accounting
of private-sector decision-making. Originally
applied to public river and harbour projects
in the USA, CBA’s contemporary uses extend
to such diverse issues as urban air quality,
dam and irrigation schemes, refuse recycling,
medical and veterinary procedures, transport
deregulation, roadway maintenance, disposal
of hazardous waste, energy generating and
conservation and job creation schemes
(Armstrong and Taylor, 2000; see also
Mishan and Quah, 2007).
Cost–benefit analysis involves three stages.
First, costs and benefits associated with
public projects have to be identified, including
intangibleexternalitiessuch as noise, habi-
tat loss, pollution and raising human
healthand lifespans. Second, these must be
quantified, including their discounting to a
common base date, since the various costs
and benefits can arise over very different time
periods. Finally, the resulting cost–benefit
ratios are incorporated into the decision-mak-
ing, or project-evaluation, stage, alongside
political and other judgmental inputs
(Turner, 2007).
Economists differ as to the best application
of these general principles in particular cases,
and over the validity of the exercise as a whole.
Defining all costs and benefits is one such:
how to be comprehensive without double-
counting. Not all variables have an obvious
marketvalue, and some ‘estimates’ may be
little more than guesses. The discount
rate can also be crucial to the outcome, and
endangers undervaluing the welfare of future
generations. Finally, distributional issues are
important – a $1 million benefit to poor
residents from one freeway route should out-
weigh the same gain to rich citizens from an
alternative.
Recent extensions of cost–benefit analysis to
large-scale environmental issues, such as
global warming, are now at the forefront of
international debate (Stern, 2007) but have
proved particularly controversial. Not only
are such potential environmental changes
irreversible, but the cost and benefits vary
internationally, raise sharp ethical valuation
judgements (e.g. over landscape, wildlife
and human life) and questions of inter- and
intra-generational fairness – the already poor
are likely to suffer most, while the future
generations who feel the sharp end of global

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_C Final Proof page 118 31.3.2009 9:45pm

COST STRUCTURE
Free download pdf