Thedifferences and merits of balanced and
unbalanced growth, and how each was
related to the necessity for a ‘big push’ to
trigger economic growth. Nurkse (1953),
like Rodenstein-Rodan, emphasized the
need for coordinated increase in the
amount of capital utilized in a wide range
of industries if industrialization was to be
achieved. Hirschmann (1958), while
agreeing with Nurske and others, also ar-
gued that unbalanced growth could,
through linkage effects, generate innov-
ations created by market responses to
shortage and surpluses.
The potential, as Lewis (1984) indicated,
forsurplus labour as a stimulant to growthin
so-calleddual economies.
The significance of saving at particular
historical moments in order to enter what
Rostow (Rostow) called the ‘take-off stage’
of industrialization.
Growth theory, from the vantage point of the
neo-liberalrevolution of the 1980s, appears
as an instance of Keynesian internationalism
in which market failures, planning, social cap-
ital and some aspects ofpolitical economy
are put to the service of ‘developing’ the
poorer nations of the world. All of these
growth theorists identified key developmental
issues – equilibrium, social overhead capital,
planning – which have continued to be ob-
jects of debate, and each (perhaps with the
exception of Rostow) contributed to both the
building of postwar multilateral development
institutions and to the idea, which in a way
was crushed by the weight of the Cold War, of
a sort of liberal developmental international-
ism (seeliberalism). In the 1980s, a ‘new
growth theory’ emerged in which endogenous
growth can occur especially through human
capital and new technologies (rather than
being assumed, as in neo-classical appro-
aches, by an exogenous savings rate or rate
of progress of technical change). mw
Suggested reading
Cypher and Dietz (1997); Preston (1996).
Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_G Final Proof page 322 2.4.2009 6:30pm
GROWTH THEORY