The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: VPugazhenthi Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_M Date:1/4/
09 Time:15:19:33 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/
revises/9781405132879_4_M.3d


and Johnson, 2005), nobody seems to question
itshegemony: as Gramsci might have put it,
there has been a Hayekian ‘passive revolution’
from above as (Silver and Arrighi, 2003).
We have witnessed what the Left’s great pessim-
ist Perry Anderson (2000c) has dubbed a ‘neo-
liberal grand slam’, withneo-liberalismruling
undivided across the globe as the
most successful ideology in world history
(Anderson, 2002c). This ‘fluent vision’ of the
Right has no equivalent on the Left: Anderson
cedes that embedded liberalism(let alone some-
thing called socialism) is now as remote as
‘Arian bishops’, resistances are like ‘chafe
in the wind’ and the Left can only ‘shelter
under the skies of infinite justice’. Of course,
with the vertiginous collapse of Wall Street and
a raft of financial institutions in late 2008, fol-
lowed by the massive bailouts initiated by vari-
ous governments in Europe and America,
Anderson’s grand slam now looks very different.
The very process by which neo-liberal mar-
ket hegemony was established – and against
which forms ofresistanceare to be assessed –
remains a story for which at present we have
no full genealogy. The cast of characters may
be lined up – from the school of Austrian
economics to the Reagan–Thatcher–Kohl
troika – but this explains very little. Neo-
liberalism can be seen as aclassreaction to
thecrisisof the 1970s. The global multilat-
erals and the Treasury–Wall Street certainly
imposed brutal forms of economic discipline –
structural adjustment– to eradicate forever
any residue of collectivism in the Third World.
But beyond these general descriptions we are
left with paradoxes and questions, of which I
will list just a few. Why did the LSE and
Chicago – the centres of Fabianism and a
certain sort of American liberalism – become
the forcing houses of neo-liberalism? Hayek,
after all, was not associated with the Econom-
ics Department; it was the arrival of Ronald
Coase at Chicago that marked a neo-liberal
turning point. How did the World Bank – a
bastion of postwar development economics
and a certain sort of statism – become the voice
oflaissez faire? Harry Johnson (who held
Chairs at the LSE and Chicago) certainly fig-
ures in the process, but how can we explain
economic liberalism’s capture of key sectors of
the Bank (often by second-rate economists)
against a backdrop of robust Keynesianism?
How did the ideas of economists such as Peter
Bauer and Deepak Lal gain traction? Criticism
of Keynes dovetailed with the anti-statism lev-
elled by many on the Left during the 1970s.
In other words, tracing the ways in which

government failures came to outweigh market
failures in development thinking demands a
complex picture of discursive contestations
and political practices. Indeed, by the mid- to
late 1970s many of neo-liberalism’s intell-
ectual architects (Milton Friedmann among
them) claimed that nobody took their ideas
seriously – Hayek believed thatThe road to
serfdomhad ruined his career and marginal-
ized his entire project. It was the inflation of
the 1970s, said Friedmann, that revealed the
cracks within the Keynesian edifice. The point
is that the ‘neo-liberal grand slam’ was pre-
ceded by decades of mediocrity, pessimism
and contestation, and that the class forces
around and through which embedded lib-
eralism had been built necessarily shaped
the manner and forms in which the counter-
revolution could proceed (if at all). How to
think about the power of themarket now
turns on how one sees this long march through
institutions. The catastrophic collapse of the
US investment banks and the discrediting of
the various regulatory and financial rating
agencies – with the prospect of a 1930s-style
world depression in the offing – suggests that
the neo-liberal project has come crashing to a
halt. As theNew York Timesput it in early
2009, ‘we are all Keynesians now’. mw

Suggested reading
Elyachar (2005); Prasad (2006); Scabas (2007).

Markov process (or Markov chain) A type
ofstochastic processin which the probabil-
ity of being in a particular state at timetis
wholly dependent upon the state(s) at some
preceding time(s). It is named after the
Russian mathematician who first defined the
process. The simplest form, known as a first-
order Markov process, is where the depend-
ence is entirely on just the immediately pre-
ceding state. This process can be represented
by a transition probability matrix in which the
rows and columns represent the different
states and the cells represent the probabilities
of movement between states. For example,
migration movements between three regions
A, B and C could be modelled as follows:

State at time t þ 1

ABC
State at timet A 0.80 0.15 0.05
B 0.08 0.90 0.02
C 0.10 0.05 0.85

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_M Final Proof page 443 1.4.2009 3:19pm

MARKOV PROCESS (OR MARKOV CHAIN)
Free download pdf