The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: VPugazhenthi Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_N Date:31/
3/09 Time:15:13:07 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/
3B2/revises/9781405132879_4_N.3d


standards of the economists’ (Krugman,
1995b, p. 88). In his manifesto, Krugman
(2000, p. 51) identifies ‘a slogan’ for his pro-
ject: ‘Dixit–Stiglitz, icebergs, evolution, and
the computer.’ Dixit–Stiglitz is the ‘clever
model’; icebergs refers to the ‘technical trick’
for introducingtransport costs(and hence
geography), evolution points to the dynamic
character of the models (as opposed to the static
kind characterizing traditionallocation the-
ory), and the computer simulates solutions
for multiple equilibria (Krugman says that his
laptop ‘lets me produce a paper – equations,
simulations and all – in a hotel room over a
weekend. ..’ (Krugman, 1995a, p. 37).
There was a precedent for the New Eco-
nomic Geography in regional science,
which was established in the 1950s to apply
rigour, scientific analysis and statistical
methods to a space economy. Unsurprisingly,
given the attempt to occupy the same terrain,
the two movements have an uncomfortable
relation. Krugman implies that regional scien-
tists have yet to find ‘clever models’, while
regional scientists dismiss Krugman’s work
by claiming that ‘it’s obvious, it’s wrong, and
anyway [it was] said years ago’ (Isserman,
1996). The relationship between the New
Economic Geography andeconomic geog-
raphyas practised inhuman geographyis
also uneasy. There was an initial flush of
interest represented by the publication of a
joint reader,The Oxford handbook of economic
geography (Clark, Gertler and Feldman,
2000), and a new journal, the Journal of
Economic Geography, which started publishing
in January 2005. Both organs promoted
cross-disciplinary exchange. At least as meas-
ured by citation impact scores, the new journal
attracted large numbers of readers from both
economic geography and economics. But
being between the same covers does not
prove intercourse, and Martin’s (1999b,
p. 70) verdict on the New Economic Geog-
raphy, that it produces a ‘dull sense ofde ́ja`vu’,
is still likely to be shared by many economic
geographers. The more than 100-year history
of economic geography is littered with failed
attempts to engage economists. This is turning
out to be another one. tb

Suggested reading
Martin (1999b).

New International Division of Labour
(NIDL) A recasting of the internationaldiv-
ision of labourassociated with the inter-
nationalization of capital and the growth of

newly industrializing countries and regions.
In one sense, the term is unhelpful, for the
uneven developmentofcapitalismensures
that the global division of labour is constantly
changing. As Marx and Engels (2002 [1848])
put it inThe communist manifesto, ‘All that is
solid melts into air.’ In another sense, how-
ever, the phrase has some merit. Particularly
in the heyday of the Bretton Woods system
(1944–73), neithercapitalnor labour moved
extensively across the global stage. National
economies were placed squarely at the heart
of an international trading system. This was
partly in response to a reading of the
Depression years and the Second World War.
The Bretton Woods system was meant to pro-
tect national space economies in the ‘First
World’ against undue economic and political
turbulence (Corbridge, 1994). When the
Bretton Woods system came undone, it gave
way to high unemployment and inflation.
According to Fro ̈bel, Heinrichs and Kreye
(1980), many capitalist firms in the West now
had to face the consequences of the postwar
corporatist settlement – a settlement that had
increased returns to labour, including labour
employed by the state, relative to those
returned to capital. Firms could evaporate,
innovate or emigrate. With the emigration of
capital, they reasoned, came a change in the
international division of labour that was dis-
tinctive – new – when viewed against the
period from 1950 to 1975.
There is no doubt that the rise of newly
industrialized countries such as Taiwan and
South Korea came as a shock in the 1970s
(see asian miracles/tigers). Some versions
ofdependency theorymaintained that the
developmentof the core depended upon the
continued non-industrialization of the periph-
ery. Gunder Frank argued that Taiwan and
South Korea were exceptions to a rule that
still held. They had simply been allowed to
develop by the USA for geopolitical reasons.
Less blinkered theories accepted thatgeopol-
iticswas part of the story, but they also noted
the way in which the state in both countries
had achieved a degree of relative autonomy
from domestic proprietary classes. They had
used this power to effect land reforms and
proactive industrial policies. In the case of
South Korea, industrial policy was fastened
mainly around large-scale domestic capitals,
including leading banks andchaebolsuch as
Samsung. In Taiwan, industrial development
was sponsored by networks of small-scale
firms (Kohli, 2004). What NIDL theorists
have added to this mix – and their work has

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_N Final Proof page 500 31.3.2009 3:13pm Compositor Name: ARaju

NEW INTERNATIONAL DIVISION OF LABOUR (NIDL)
Free download pdf