The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_P Date:1/4/09
Time:15:20:49 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/re-
vises/9781405132879_4_P.3d


geography, rooted inecosystemsapproaches
to human behaviour; ecological anthropology,
grounded in cybernetics and the adaptive
qualities of living systems (see Rappaport,
1968); and the high tide of Marxist-inspired
political economy, andpeasantstudies in
particular, of the 1970s. A number of people
contributed to this intersection of ideas –
Richards’ (1985) work on peasant science,
Hecht’s (1985) analysis of eastern Amazonia,
Grossman (1984) on subsistence in Papua
New Guinea, and Watts (1983) on the simple
reproduction squeeze and drought in Nigeria –
but Blaikie pulled a number of disparate
themes and ideas together, drawing in large
measure on his own South Asian experiences.
In rejecting thecolonialmodel of soil erosion
that framed the problem around environmen-
tal constraints, mismanagement,overpopula-
tionandmarketfailure, Blaikie started from
the resource manager, and specifically house-
holds from whom surpluses are extracted,
‘who then in turn are forced to extract
‘‘surpluses’’ from the environment ... [lead-
ing] to degradation’ (1985, p. 124). The ana-
lytical scaffolding was provided by a number of
key middle-range concepts – marginalization,
proletarianization and incorporation – that
permitted geographers to see the failure of soil
conservation schemes inclassor social terms;
namely, thepowerof classes affected by soil
erosion in relation tostatepower, the class-
specific perception of soil problems and solu-
tions, and the class basis of soil erosion as a
political issue. Blaikie was able to drive home
the point thatpovertycould, in a dialectical
way, cause degradation – ‘peasants destroy
their own environment in attempts to delay
their own destruction’ (1985, p. 29) – and that
poverty had to be understood not as a thing or
a condition, but as the social relations of pro-
duction, which are realms of possibility and
constraint.
In this work, political ecology came to mean
a combination of ‘the concerns ofecology
and a broadly defined political economy’
(Blaikie and Brookfield, 1987, p. 17), the lat-
ter understood as a concern with effects ‘on
people, as well as on their productive activ-
ities, of on-going changes within society at
local and global levels’ (1987, p. 21). This is
a broad definition – an approach rather than a
theory – which was adopted by the editors in
the inaugural issue of theJournal of Political
Ecologyin 1995. Political ecology has three
essential foci.
The first is interactive, contradictory and
dialectical:societyandland-basedresources

are mutually causal in such a way that poverty,
via poor management, can induce environmen-
tal degradation that itself deepens poverty. Less
a problem of poor management, inevitable nat-
ural decay or demographic growth (seede-
mography), land degradation is seen associal
in origin and definition. Analytically, the cen-
trepoint of any nature–society study must be
the ‘land manager’, whose relationship to
nature must be considered in a historical, pol-
itical and economic context.
Second, political ecology argues for regional
or spatial accounts of degradation that link,
through ‘chains of explanation’, local decision-
makers to spatial variations in environmental
structure (stability and resilience as traits of
particular ecosystems in particular).locality
studies are, thus, subsumed within multi-
layered analyses pitched at a variety of regional
scales.
Third, land management is framed by
‘external structures’, which for Blaikie meant
the role of the state and thecore__periphery
model.
If early political ecology was not exactly clear
what political economy implied, beyond a sort
of 1970sdependency theory, it did provide a
number of principles and mid-range concepts.
The first is a refined concept of marginality in
which its political, ecological and economic
aspects may be mutually reinforcing: land deg-
radation is both a result and a cause of social
marginalization. Second, pressure of produc-
tion on resources is transmitted through social
relations, which impose excessive demands on
theenvironment(i.e.surplus extraction). And
third, the inadequacy of environmental data of
historical depth linked to a chain ofexplan-
ation analysis compels a plural approach.
Rather than unicausal theories one must, in
short, accept ‘plural perceptions, plural defin-
itions ... and plural rationalities’ (Blaikie and
Brookfield, 1987, p. 16).
Political ecology had the advantage of see-
ing land management and environmental deg-
radation (orsustainability) in terms of how
political economy shapes the ability to manage
resources (through forms of access and con-
trol, of exploitation), and through the lens of
cognition (one person’s accumulation is
another person’s degradation). But in other
respects political ecology was demonstrably
weak: it often had an outdated notion ofecol-
ogyand ecological dynamics (including an
incomplete understanding of ecological
agency: Zimmerer, 1994b); it was often remark-
ably silent on the politics of political ecology; it
had a somewhat voluntarist notion of human

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_P Final Proof page 546 1.4.2009 3:20pm

POLITICAL ECOLOGY
Free download pdf