The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_P Date:1/4/09
Time:15:20:51 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/re-
vises/9781405132879_4_P.3d


is primarily associated with the French School
ofhuman geographythat had its roots in the
writings of Paul Vidal de la Blache (1845–
1918), but also found favour in Britain in the
early-twentieth-century work of Patrick
Geddes and H.J. Fleure, and in the USA in
Carl Ortin Sauer’s insistence on the trans-
formative power of humanculture(see also
berkeley school). It thus stands in contrast
toenvironmental determinismand was clas-
sically expressed in Lucien Febvre’s dictum
‘There are no necessities, but everywhere pos-
sibilities; and man, as master of the possibil-
ities, is the judge of their use’ (Febvre, 1932,
p. 27). Different philosophical roots of the
doctrine have been identified, including neo-
Kantian philosophy (see kantianism:
Berdoulay, 1976), probability theory associ-
ated with Poincare ́(Lukermann, 1965), and
Lamarckian biology (see lamarck(ian)ism:
Archer, 1993). Differences between possibi-
lism, environmental determinism and prob-
abilism are more easily identified when taken
asideal typesrather than as operational per-
spectives in geographical research. dnl

Suggested reading
Lukermann (1965).

Postan thesis A major interpretation of the
dynamic of the medievaleconomy, proposed
by historian Michael Postan (1898–1981).
The thesis was first developed for England,
but subsequently extended to cover much of
Westerneurope. Postan’s ideas derived from
classical political economy, particularly
Ricardo and Malthus, which he saw as a
framework for understanding the links
between population, landedresourcesand
living standards over the long term (Postan,
1966, 1972; Hatcher and Bailey, 2001; see
malthusian model). In so doing, he reacted
negatively to linear interpretations of the
medieval economy that were underwritten by
a belief in the progressive growth of themar-
ket and monetization as frameworks for
understanding change. Indeed, the thesis was
eventually utilized as a means of understand-
ing both European medieval and early modern
pre-industrial economies (Le Roy Ladurie,
1966; Abel, 1980).
Postan accepted classical political economic
assumptions about the fixity of land supply as
a factor of production, minimal technological
innovation in farming and diminishing returns
to increased labour inputs. As a result, he
viewed population growth to be unsustainable
in the long term, as it led to an oversupply of

labour on the land and fragmentation of land
holdings. Consequently, he argued that as a
result of population growth over the thir-
teenth century, associated with real wage falls
and shrinkage of holding sizes, an increasingly
harvest-sensitive population emerged that was
vulnerable to periodic crises (Postan and
Titow, 1958–9). These were observable in a
consistent tendency for death rates to rise
with grain prices and responsible for cataclys-
mic phases such as the Great European
famine of 1315–22. Furthermore, he was
inclined to see susceptibility to high death
rates associated withepidemicdisease such
as the Black Death as a manifestation of
society’s vulnerability resulting from an
imbalance between population and resource
available per capita. Postan added other
elements to this interpretation, such as a belief
in the decline of soil fertility that arose as
populations cropped land too frequently and
nitrogen levels plummeted, driving communi-
ties to cultivate soil types that were inherently
unsuitable for arable farming and grain
production. He believed that population
decline in the fourteenth century was a
punishment for ‘overfishing’ in the previous
century, and that the damage done to soil
fertility was not repaired until at least the
sixteenth century when population totals
began again to recover.
Since Postan’s death, historians and histor-
ical geographers have contested the idea that
technology was unchanging and argued that
the thirteenth- and early fourteenth-century
economy was showing signs of developing spe-
cialization and genuinecomparative advan-
tages in a manner more consistent with
Smithian growth theory (Britnell, 1993;
Britnell and Campbell, 1995). It has also been
argued, in conformity with the boserup
thesis, that in densely populated areas of
England grain yields were increased by an
increase in labour inputs as land was cropped,
weeded and fertilised more frequently
(Campbell, 1983, 2000). Others have sought
alternative explanations for weakness in the
economy associated with seigneurial exploit-
ation through the removal of surpluses legit-
imated by serfdom as a relation of production
(seebrenner thesis). More recently, it has
been claimed that the difficulties associated
with harvest failure were in many instances
caused by extreme natural events that would
have impacted adversely on any pre-industrial
economy (Bailey, 1992). It has also been
argued that exogenously generated epidemic
disease that brought down population

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_P Final Proof page 560 1.4.2009 3:20pm

POSTAN THESIS
Free download pdf