The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_P Date:1/4/09
Time:15:20:52 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/re-
vises/9781405132879_4_P.3d


economic growth, but also to better educa-
tional provision and healthcare delivery,
including for HIV/AIDS patients.
Not everyone agrees with Sachs’ vision of
what causes absolute poverty (he directs a lot
of attention tophysical geography) or his
suggestion that it is best addressed by massive
programmes of public spending (see also
development). Part of the reason for this is
that Sachs is mainly concerned with calorific
or income poverty. Adam Smith famously
argued that a definition of poverty should
include the right not to feel shame in public.
In other words, he recognized that people can-
not function in ways that they might want to if
they are the targets of physical or verbal abuse.
This tradition of thinking has been continued
by John Maynard Keynes and Amartya Sen.
One virtue of Sen’s (2000) work is that it
directs us to think about poverty in relational


  • and not simply absolute – terms. What mat-
    ters, Sen suggests, is whether we have the
    capability to live our lives in ways that we
    consider meaningful, however differently we
    might define what a meaningful life is. This
    is partly qualified, for Sen, by the prior
    requirement that all human beings must have
    a minimal level of food intake, shelter, educa-
    tion and health to function as humans. One
    can imagine a family in Punjab, then, that is
    above a state-defined poverty line. Perhaps the
    family has benefited from rising incomes as a
    result of thegreen revolution. But what if
    females in the family lose paid jobs to male
    kin, perhaps on the basis that their labour in
    the fields is no longer ‘required’? What if this
    loss of earning power translates into a system
    ofpurdah, where women find it harder to ven-
    ture into public space? For Sen, this can also
    be a sign of poverty, precisely because it
    defines a gendered system ofsocial exclu-
    sion. The same argument can be extended to
    members of social groups who are not allowed
    to worship with others, or who cannot easily
    draw water from public wells (Erb and
    Harriss-White, 2002).
    This way of thinking about poverty also dir-
    ects attention to social norms and thus to the
    geographical nature of poverty. In richer coun-
    tries, ‘poverty’ is most commonly defined as
    relative deprivation, and here as elsewhere it
    tends to be feminized (Jones and Kodras,
    1990; but see also Chant, 2006). People are
    considered to be poor relative to some
    assumed bundle of goods or services, or of
    capabilities and functionings, that provides
    for at least a minimum level of access to what
    is considered ‘normal’ in a given social setting.


For example, in the USA, not having a televi-
sion set might be considered an index both of
social exclusion and of relative deprivation, at
least where this is not an active family choice.
Once the word ‘normal’ comes into play, how-
ever, we recognize that ‘wars on poverty’ are
discursive constructions and not just political
campaigns (Yapa, 1998: see discourse).
Social scientists now pay close attention to
the powers ofstateand non-state actors to
define ‘poverty’. They also look at the govern-
mental effects of describing someone as poor
or, as in India, as a Below Poverty Line (BPL)
person or household (Corbridge, Williams,
Srivastava and Ve ́ron, 2005). Work on these
issues is being published alongside academic
research on poverty, inequality andglobal-
izationin the world economy (Wade, 2004;
Wolf, 2004). There is clearly room for both
types of work: for studies that are sharply
attentive to the cultural constructions of pov-
erty and its effects in different locations, and
for studies that carefully seek to map out what
has been happening to absolute poverty in the
developing world (with and without consider-
ations of India and China, whose enormous
size affects all calculations) in an age of appar-
ently increased spatial interdependencies.sco

Suggested readings
Gordon and Spicker (1999); Jones (2004a);
Sachs (2005); World Bank (2001).

poverty gap poverty is conventionally
measured in terms of an Absolute Poverty
Line, expressed in monetary terms: it is the
income or expenditure below which a min-
imum nutritionally adequate diet plus essen-
tial non-food requirements are no longer
affordable (e.g. spending per capita of less
than US$1.00 a day, which is the conventional
measure or threshold for the Absolute Poverty
Line everywhere). A poverty line distin-
guishes, then, the poor from the non-poor
(Ravallion, 1995; UNDP, 1998). Poverty esti-
mates are typically based on data from actual
household budget or income/expenditure
surveys. In this way, a proportion of a coun-
try’s population or an absolute number of per-
sons or households can be designated as living
in absolute poverty: this is theHead Count
Index. Currently, for example, it is estimated
that 47 per cent of the population in Nigeria
live in absolute poverty. Using this Absolute
Poverty Line, it is possible to calculate what
proportion of the GDP of a country would be
required to lift those in absolute poverty above
the poverty line (e.g. the proportion of

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_P Final Proof page 574 1.4.2009 3:20pm

POVERTY GAP
Free download pdf