The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_P Date:1/4/09
Time:15:20:52 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/re-
vises/9781405132879_4_P.3d


Nigeria’s GDP that would be required to lift
the 70 millions who are absolutely poor to a
condition in which their basic needs were ful-
filled). This is thepoverty gap: the poorer the
country and the larger the number of people in
poverty, the greater is the gap (i.e. the
resourcesthat must be devoted to raise those
in poverty). The poverty gap thus speaks to
the scale and depth of poverty, and what it
would take as a measure of national output
to bring all of the population above the poverty
line. ThePoverty Gap Ratiorefers to the mean
distance below the $1 a day poverty line
expressed as a percentage of the poverty line
(currently 34 per cent for Nigeria). The
Poverty Gap Indexrefers to additional money
the average poor person would have to spend
(in aggregate or as a proportion of total con-
sumption) in order to reach the poverty line.
The poverty gap for India is currently 4 per
cent, for China 1 per cent and for eastern
Europe 0.1 per cent. The Poverty Severity
Indexmeasures the distribution of welfare of
those below the poverty line (i.e. between the
poor and the ultra-poor). mw

power A minimal definition of power would
refer to the ability of one agent to affect the
actions or attitudes of another. Like most con-
cepts that are central to social science, the
meanings, causes and effects of power are con-
tinually being re-assessed. One thing we know
for sure is that it is trite to think of power only
in negative terms. The possibility of having a
conversation with someone, of running a class
or seminar in which people can learn, of play-
ing a football match, depends upon the
deployment of power: of people taking turns
to speak and listen, of students and teachers
doing work as agreed, of players deferring to a
referee. People both exercise power and are on
the receiving end of power at different times
every day, in all realms of life. More important
than the fact that power is exercised is the way
in which power is constructed and deployed.
To what extent is power concentrated in cer-
tain institutions, relationships or agencies?
How visible is it? What are the opportunities
for power relations to be contested or rotated?
Are accountability mechanisms in place, and if
so how well do they work?
The idea that power is fundamentally nega-
tive continues to be a powerful one, even when
it is coupled with an idea of necessary
restraint. Thomas Hobbes (1968 [1651])
argued that all men (sic) acted as egoists, bent
on the satisfaction of their desires through
relentless power plays. Given a world of

scarcity, only the sovereign could prevent
these individualized acts of power from adding
up to an intolerablestate of nature(cf.sov-
ereign power). Contemporary work on
international relations by so-called
Realists presents a similar view of power, in
which all states seek to maximize their self-
interest and are prepared to use violence to
this end. Anarchy is prevented only by the
exercise ofhegemonyby a dominant power.
Some versions ofmarxismcome close to this
argument. Marxists argue that capitalist
statesdeploy their power to guarantee the
accumulationprocess under the rule ofcap-
ital. It is not surprising, then, that many
Realists and Marxists share the view that the
war in Iraq was fundamentally aboutoiland
the protection of America’s self-interest. As
David Harvey puts it inThe new imperialism,
joining Marx to Mackinder, ‘Whoever controls
themiddle eastcontrols the global oil spigot
and whoever controls the global oil spigot can
control the global economy, at least for the
near future’ (2003b, p. 19).
Of course, there is more to Marxism on
power than a perspective on international rela-
tions. Marxist work on power inhuman geog-
raphyfirst made its mark through a critique of
behavioural and pluralist models of power.
These models, developed by political scientists
such as Robert Dahl to look at power coali-
tions in US cities, emphasized the overt and
dispersed nature of power. Power could be
observed when A made an open attempt to
force B to do something that s/he would not
otherwise do. If A succeeded, s/he had power
in this ‘issue area’. Happily, however, or so
Dahl (1963) concluded, B would probably
exercise power over A in another issue area.
Given the nature ofdemocracyin the USA,
power was hard to monopolize.
Radical scholars disagreed. Steven Lukes
(2005) argued that this view of power was
one-dimensional. The work of power was
most often done in smoke-filled rooms and in
the setting of agendas. Lukes referred to this as
two-dimensional power, and he did not stop
there. Lukes further argued, as did many
Marxist geographers (see marxist geog-
raphy), that not only were agendas bent to
serve certainclassinterests (not least through
the state), but also that many people at the
wrong end of power were unable to see their
powerlessness. In part, this is because of what
Marxists call ‘false consciousness’. Ordinary
people cannot see their ‘objective interests’,
because their political antennae have been
deadened by years of watching sport, shopping

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_P Final Proof page 575 1.4.2009 3:20pm

POWER
Free download pdf