The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_P Date:1/4/09
Time:15:20:56 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/re-
vises/9781405132879_4_P.3d


(Hubbard, 2004). In all cases, research sug-
gests the gendered inequalities of sexual
commerce produces a series of spaces where
women’s sexuality can be bought and sold by
men with relative impunity, albeit that these
spaces may be important in the forging of new
gender identities and formations (Law,
1997). In this sense, the relative silence on
forms of male sex work poses some interesting
questions about gender inequalities within and
without the discipline. ph

Suggested reading
Hubbard (1999).

proto-industrialization A term proposed by
economic historian Franklin Mendels (1972)
to denote ‘the rapid growth of traditionally
organised but market-oriented, principally
rural industry’. Whilst the presence of such
industries had long been recognized,
Mendels presented proto-industrialization
not merely as a description of (pre-)industrial
organization, but also as anexplanationof
industrial change, arguing that it ‘preceded
and prepared for’ industrialization.In
emphasizing the continuities between trad-
itional systems of domestic production and
the centralized and mechanized factory sys-
tem, Mendels’ thesis is central to the broader
reconceptualization ofindustrial revolution
as an evolutionary and gradual process. Two
different models have been proposed, each
with its own empirical and conceptual
emphasis. Ecological models focus on the
pre-conditions for proto-industrialization, par-
ticularly the ways in which under-employed
peasantlabour was drawn into industrial pro-
duction. There is little consensus on the type of
agrarian economy that would favour such
development, with rural industries emerging
in both arable areas (with seasonal unemploy-
ment) and pastoral regions (with diurnal time-
budgets). In reality, much depended upon the
social and institutional environment of the
area, especially land holding and the type and
flexibility of labour skills. Once established, it
is argued thatcomparative advantageled to a
growingdivision of labourbetween specialist
industrial and agriculturalregions. However,
this not only makes unwarranted assumptions
about individual and collective rationality, but
also fails to acknowledge the importance of
other variables, such as the presence of com-
mercialized mercantile and urban networks
(Stobart, 2004).
Economic modelsfocus on the structural rela-
tionship between the peasant/artisan and the

merchant/capitalist. The artisanhousehold
sought to balance production and consump-
tion by adjusting the level of engagement in
manufacture for themarket, whilst the mer-
chant collected together the products of
domestic labour and consigned them to dis-
tant markets. Although mutually dependent,
the interests of these two parties were inher-
ently contradictory. When prices fell, artisans
increased production to maintain household
income, thus saturating the market and wor-
sening the recession. When prices rose, artisan
households could more easily satisfy their
needs and production slowed, just when mer-
chants would seek to take advantage of
increased profits. This conflict is seen as being
resolved through the increasing control exer-
cised by merchants over the production pro-
cess. Initially, this involved a shift from the
Kaufsystemof independent artisan production
to theVerlagssytemof putting out, wherein the
means of production remained in the hands of
the merchant, who effectively employed
dependent outworkers. This was subsequently
superseded by a merchant-led centralization
of production into proto-factories (Kriedte,
Medick and Schlumbohm, 1981).
This version of proto-industrialization as a
theory of industrial change has been chal-
lenged from three very different directions.
At the level of the peasant household, de
Vries (1994) has argued that consumption as
well as production became ever-more market
oriented, increasing household specialization
and growing consumption inspiring an
artisan-centred ‘industrious revolution’. At a
broader scale, studies of regional industrializa-
tion have emphasized that the logic ofcapit-
alismwas played out differently in different
places: factory production was one of a range
of possibilities, which included workshop-
based flexible specialization as well as hybrid
factory–workshop systems (Berg, 1994). More
fundamentally, others have questioned
whether proto-industrialization was, indeed,
a necessary stage in industrial development,
arguing that the switch from organic to
mineralresourceswas the real key to indus-
trialization. jst

Suggested reading
Berg, Hudson and Sonenscher (1983); Houston
and Snell (1984).

psychoanalytic theory Originating in the
late nineteenth century in the work of
Sigmund Freud (1986–1939), psychoanalytic
theory and practice offers a distinctive way of

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_P Final Proof page 595 1.4.2009 3:20pm

PSYCHOANALYTIC THEORY
Free download pdf